• Ei tuloksia

Consideration using implied normal-jump variation

5.4 Numerical scrutinies for modelling volatility

5.4.2 Consideration using implied normal-jump variation

This subsection shows a straightforward approach to model variation in the risk-free xed income market. As was noted in the introduction, the use of normal jump-diusion models is suitable in the market situation described in the previous subsection. Using these models, the combination of low rates and high volatility can be handled.

For the example of this section the data of March 31st, 2015 has been used. The swaption prices are quoted for ve dierent swap tenors (2, 5, 10,

20, and 30 years), for six dierent option expiries (3 months and 1, 5, 10, 20,and 30 years) and for eight degrees of moneyness dened as strike minus the forward swap rate (-100 bps, -50bps, -25bps, ATM, 25bps, 50bps, 100bps and 200bps). Black volatilities especially for short maturities and tenors, are high, as can be seen in Figure 5.3 in the appendix.

The parameters of the model in equation (5.3.6) are the same for all maturity and tenor combinations: λ = 0.075, a = 0.3 and b = 0.6. The values of implied volatilities using the pricing formula of Theorem II are shown in the Figure 5.4.

The values of Black volatility are shown in Figure 5 in the appendix.

Dierences between strikes as well as between consecutive expiries and tenors are high. Implied volatilities for rates near zero are highly sensitive. To apply these volatilities to interest risk analysis is dicult.

The implied volatilities of the normal-jump model are much less sensitive and dierences between consecutive values are modest. These more robust values are also more applicable for risk analysis, e.g. for calculation of risk measures. Figure 6 in the appendix shows the normal-jump implied volatility values divided by forward swap rates times 100, which are easier to compare to the Black model's volatilities.

Local volatility tting

As Figure 5.4 shows, the normal jump-diusion model cannot explain the skewness of volatility. The values of volatility are typically smallest near strikes. The volatility becomes higher as the strike becomes smaller or higher.

This is a common observation for implied volatility models. The case is sim-ilar when log-normal jump-diusion is used. The values of volatilities consti-tute smile or smirk depending on the choice of parameters (see Glasserman and Kou, 2003, p. 395).

This subsection gives one obvious next step for the analysis of this sec-tion and show a straightforward method to model the constant volatility. The method for calibrating volatility skewness has been considered, e.g. by

Cole-man et al. (1999), Andersen and Andreasen (2001), Benaim et al. (2008).

This example uses the pricing model of Theorem II and ts a model using an ordinary least square method (follows Coleman et al. (1999)):

mina,bΣiu(Ki)−σˆu(Ki))2, (5.4.1) where σu(Ki):s are volatilities for dierent strikes. σˆu(K) is dened by the functionaebK. The solutions have been found separately for dierent expiry and tenor. The function is extremely simple but it gives a reasonably good t. A more complicated function presented in Benaim (2008) gives a slightly better t. The values for parameters a and b are shown in Figure 7 in the appendix. It is possible to use the tted functions for extrapolation to complete the data.

5.5 Conclusion

The assumption of log-normality is typical for the HJM- and LIBOR- interest models. This assumption has three fundamental problems: it ignores the jumps of underlying time series, it assumes constant volatilities and it is unwieldy in the low (or negative) rate environment. This paper has presented an approach to solving all these problems by combining the jump-diusion model with normality assumption and local volatility tting. This approach is the rst presented in the literature to combine Bachelier's option pricing model and a jump process. Obviously, more complicated models using those elements could be developed, but the purpose of this paper has focused on nding as simple a method as possible for tackling those three problems.

.0.1 Appendix

Figure 5: Implied Black volatilities (source: Bloomberg)

Figure 6: Ratios of normal jump-diusion volatilities and forward swap rate as percents

Figure 7: Values for parameters a and b in section 4.2.1

.1 Symbol description

Et expectation given information available at time t Wt standard Brownian motion

Φ(y) the cumulative density function of standard normal distribution r(t) spot rate at time t

P(t, T) the price at time t of a zero-coupon bond which pays a principle of one at time T and no other payments

f(t, T) instantaneous forward rate

L(t, S, T)simple forward rate at time tfor period [S, T] δ xed accrual period

α(t, T)the drift of forward rate process σ(t, T) the volatility of forward rate process f instantaneous forward rate

Sm,n(T)forward swap rate at time T, with the payment datesTm, Tm+1, ..., Tn Am,n(T)annuity at time T, with the payment dates Tm, Tm+1, ..., Tn

CBSis swaption price under log-normal distributed underlying forward swap rate

CJ is swaption price when forward swap rate follows log-normal distribution with jumps

α0(t, T) the drift of swap rate process θ(t, T) the volatility of swap rate process Other necessary denitions are in the text.

Bibliography

[1] APPLEBAUM, D. (2004): Lévy processes-from probability to nance and quantum groups, 1336 Notices of the AMS V51, number 11.

[2] ANDERSEN, L.B.G. and ANDREASEN, J (2000): Volatility Skews and Extensions of the LIBOR Market Model, Appl. Math. Finance 7, 1-32.

[3] ANDERSEN, L. and BROTHERTON-RATCLIFFE, R.(1998): The Eq-uity Option Volatility Smile: A Finite Dierence Approach. Journal of Computational Finance 1, 2, 5-38.

[4] ANDERSEN, L.B.G. and PITERBARG, V.V. (2010): Interest Rate Modelling, Volume I-III, Atlantic Financial Press.

[5] BACHELIER, L. (1900): "Théorie de la spéculation", Annales Scien-tiques de l'École Normale Supérieure 3 (17), pp. 21-86.

[6] BENAIM, S., DODGSON, M., and KAINTH, D. (2008): An arbitrage-free method for smile extrapolation. Technical report, Royal Bank of Scotland.

[7] BJÖRK, T. and KABANOV, Y. and RUNGGALDIER, W. (1997):

Bond Market Structure in the Presence of Marked Point Processes, Math. Finance, Vol. 7(2), 211-239.

[8] BLACK, F. (1975): Fact and Fantasy in the Use of Options, Financial Analysts Journal, 55-72.

[9] BLACK, F. (1976): The Pricing of CommodityContracts, Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 167-179.

[10] BLACK, F. and SCHOLES, M. (1973): The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities, Journal of Political Economy, 81, 637-654.

[11] BRIGO, D., MERCURIO, F. and RAPISARDA, F. (2004): Smile at the Uncertainty, Risk, May.

[12] CARVER, L. (2012): Negative rates: Dealers struggle to price 0% oors.

Risk Magazine, November.

[13] COLEMAN, T., LI, Y. and VERMA, A. (1999): Reconstructing the Unknown Local VolatilityFunction, Journal of Computational Finance 2, 3, 77-102.

[14] CONT, R. and TANKOV, P. (2004): Financial Modelling with Jump Processes, Chapman & Hall/CRC, Boca Raton, FL.

[15] CONT, R. and VOLTCHKOVA, E. (2005): A Finite Dierence Scheme for Option Pricing in Jump Diusion and Exponential LévyModels.

Siam J. Number. Anal. Vol 43, No. 4, 1596-1626.

[16] COX, J. C, INGERSOLL, J. E.and ROSS, S. A. (1985A): An Intertem-poral General Equilibrium Model of Asset Prices. Econometrica, 53 (March 1985a), 363-384.

[17] COX, J. C. INGERSOLL, Jr., J. E. and ROSS, S. A. (1985b): A Theory of the Term Structure of Interest Rates. Econometrica 53(2), 385-407.

[18] DUFFIE, D. (2001): Dynamic Asset Pricing Theory, Princeton, NJ : Princeton UniversityPress.

[19] ERRAIS, E. and MERCURIO, F. (2004): Yes, LIBOR models can cap-ture interest rate derivatives skew: a simple modelling approach, IMI Banca working paper, http://ssrn.com/abstract=680621.

[20] FRAMSTAD, N.C., ØKSENDAL, B., SULEM, A. (1998): Optimal con-sumption and portfolio in a jump diusion market. In: Shiryaev, A., Sulem, A. (Eds.), Proceedings of the Workshop on Mathematical Fi-nance. INRIA, Paris.

[21] GATAREK, D. (2003): LIBOR market model with stochastic volatility, Working Paper. Deloitte&Touche.

[22] GLASSERMAN, P. and KOU, S. G. (2003): TermStructure of Simple Forward Rates with Jump Risk, Math. Finance, Vol. 13, No. 3 (July), 383-410.

[23] GLASSERMAN, P. and MERENER, N. (2003): Cap and swaption ap-proximations in Libor market models with jumps, Journal of Numerical Finance, Volume 7/ Number 1, (Fall).

[24] HAGAN,P., KUMAR, D., LESNIEWSKI, A. and WOODWARD, D.

(2002): Managing Smile Risk, Risk Magazine, 84-108.

[25] HARRISON, J. M. and KREPS, D. M.(1979): Martingales and Arbi-trage in Multiperiod Securities Markets, Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 20, 381-408.

[26] HEATH, D., JARROW, R. and MORTON, A. (1992): Bond pricing and the termstructure of interest rates. Econometrica 60 No.1, 77-106.

[27] HILBER, N., REICH, N. and SCHWAB, C. and WINTER, C. (2009):

Numerical Methods for Lévy Processes. Finance Stoch 13:471-500.

[28] HULL, J. and WHITE, A (2000): Forward Rate Volatilities, Swap Rate Volatilities, and the Implementation of the Libor Market Model. NYU Working Paper No. FIN-00-023

[29] JAMSHIDIAN, F. (1997): LIBOR and swap market models and mea-sures. Finance and Stochastics. Volume 1, Issue 4, pp 293â¿330, September 1997.

[30] JOHANNES, M, S. (2004): The Statistical and Economic Role of Jumps in Interest Rates. J. Finance. Vol. LIX, No. 1, February.

[31] KOU, S.G. (2002): A Jump-diusion Model for Option Pricing. Man-agement Science. Vol. 48, No. 8, August 2002 pp. 1086-1101.

[32] LEE, R. and WANG, D. (2012): Displaced Lognormal Volatility Skews:

Analysis and Applications to Stochastic Volatility Simulations. Annals of Finance, Vol 8 (2), 159-181.

[33] MEHRA, R. and PRESCOTT E. C. (1985): The Equity Premium: A Puzzle. J. Monetary Econ. 15 (March 1985): 145-61.

[34] MERTON, R.C. (1971): Optimum Consumption and Portfolio Rules in a Continuous-Time Model. Journal of Economic Theory 3, 373-413.

[35] MERTON, R.C. (1976): Option Pricing when Underlying Stock Returns are Discontinuous. Journal of Financial Economics, May, 125-144.

[36] MERTON, R.C. (1990): Continuous-time Finance, Blackwell, Mas-sachusetts.

[37] MILTERSEN, K. R, SANDMANN, K. and SONDERMANN, D. (1997):

Closed-FormSolutions for TermStructure Derivatives with Lognormal Interest Rates, Journal of Finance, 52, 409-430.

[38] MUNK, C. (1997): Optimal Consumption/Portfolio Policies and Con-tingent Claims Pricing and Hedging in Incomplete Markets, Ph.D. dis-sertation, School of Business and Economics Odense University.

[39] MUSIELA, M. and RUTKOWSKI, M. (1997): Continuous-Time Term Structure Models: Forward Measure Approach, Finance Stoch. 1, 261-292.

[40] NAIK, V. and M. LEE. (1990): General EquilibriumPricing of Op-tions on the Market Portfolio with Discontinuous Returns, Review of Financial Studies 3, 493-521.

[41] ØKSENDAL, B. (1998): Stochastic DierentialEquations. (Fifth ed.), Springer-Verlag.

[42] ØKSENDAL, B. and SULEM A. (2007): Applied Stochastic Control of Jump Diusions. (Second ed.), Springer-Verlag.

[43] RADY, S. and SANDMANN, K. (1994): The Direct Approach to Debt Option Pricing. The Review of Futures Markets, 13(2):461-514.

[44] SCHACHERMAYER, W. and TEICHMANN, J.: How close are the option pricing formulas of Bachelier and Black-Merton-Scholes? Math.

Finance 18, 155-170 (2008)

[45] TROLLE, A. B. and SCHWARTZ, E. S. (2014): The Swaption Cube.

Review of FinancialStudies, vol. 27, no. 8, p. 2307-2353.

[46] SCHWARTZ, E.S. (1977): The Valuation of Warrants: Implementing a New Approach. Journalof FinancialEconomics, 4 (Jan. 1977), 79-93.

[47] SCOTT, L. O. (1997): Pricing Stock Options in a Jump-Diusion Model with Stochastic Volatility and Interest Rates: Applications of Fourier Inversion Methods. MathematicalFinance, Volume 7, Issue 4, pages 413-426, October 1997.

[48] WILMOTT, P.(2006): PaulWilmott On Quantitative Finance, Vol1-3, 2nd Edition, John Wiley and Sons, Ltd.