• Ei tuloksia

This paper has considered Merton's consumption and investment choice prob-lem in the case of non-addictive habits. As shown by Detemple and Karatzas (2003), for the case in which habit is non-addictive there is a signicant re-lationship between the solution with and without the non-negativity con-straint. By using the martingale representation theorem, Detemple and Za-patero (1992, p. 257-259) have proved the existence and uniqueness of the optimal portfolio of an agent with habit utilities. However, they characterize this solution only as an unknown process. Optimal consumption and portfo-lio choice of the agent with habit utility function can also be found via the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation following Egglezos (2007, p.48-50). Then

the r(t), λ(t), σ(t) have to follow Markov processes. The consideration of the previous section allows a non-Markovian framework.

The so-called habit factors a(t) and b(t) are deterministic. The optimal consumption and investment choices were shown in the general case as well as in the case of the HARA utility function. The optimal portfolio solution was found using results on isomorphism in Schroder and Skidas (2002).

Throughout this paper, I have assumed complete markets, in line with the bulk of the literature. This makes it easier to nd solutions. Obviously, this assumption is restrictive and rules out many interesting aspects of nancial markets. By using numerical methods, it is possible to relax this assumption and consider more complicated and realistic situations. Future research could consider these alternative scenarios.

Appendix

.1 Isomorphism between the separable and habit case

Schroder and Skiadas (2002) also consider the isomorphism in the case of more general market processes where stock prices and money markets can be non-Markovian processes.

The isomorphism is useful,if a primal problem is easier to solve and the solution can be reformulated to obtain the habit solution. The duality results are symmetric and the roles of primal and dual qualities are interchangeable.

The process in equation (2.4.15): ρ(t)=. Et are material for the solution. BsT is a unit discount bond that matures at time T andσBis the volatility of that bond. The solution of a primal optimization problem can be found from the dual problem

supcˆ(t)E If the dual agent's problem has been solved and the optimal consumption plan ˆc is the corresponding optimal consumption plan,the price of risk, wealth process and portfolio choice are

ˆ

and

.2 Solutions in the time separable case and in the habit in case

This derivation is a straightforward extension of the proof of Theorem 1 in appendix of Munk (2008) and proposition 1 in the appendix of Munk and Sørensen (2000). whereKand(1−K)are weights between utility in periods[t, T]and terminal utility.

According to the martingale approach, the problem can be solved as a static problem by using the Lagrange method. The rst order conditions are

Ke−υ(s−t)(βc(s)

and

Inserting equations (.2.5) and (.2.6) into the budget constraint gives w(t) =λ−1μ Et

A positive stochastic process O(t) adapted to the ltration generated by dz(t) is dened by:

The dynamics of O(t) can be described by

dO(t) =O(t)[μOtdt+σOtdz(t)]. (.2.9) Then, optimal consumption plan is

c(s) =Kμ1w(t)−L(t) and optimal terminal utility is

w(T) = w(t)−L(t)

This optimal plan for the terminal wealth in (.2.12) is valid for any t,

Following the appendix of Munk and Sørensen (2000) and using Itˆo's rule we obtain a stochastic dierential equation of an optimal investment policy

dw(t)

w(t) = [...]dt+ (1 L(t) w(t))1

μλ(t)dz+σOtdz. (.2.13) Inserting a testing equation for optimal portfolio choice

π(t) = (1− L(t)

w(t))(σ(t))−1(1

μλ(t) +σOt) (.2.14) into budget constraint equation (2.3.10)we obtain

dw(t)

w(t) = [...]dt+ [1

μλ(t) +σOt]dz. (.2.15) We can see that using the strategy (.2.14)the diusion coecients of(2.3.10) and (.2.15)match and it gives the optimal portfolio choice in the non-habit case. Under the martingale solution approach, the drift term will be matched if the diusion coecients are matched.

By next using Schroder and Skiadas's rule for optimal portfolio choice (2.5.2), we obtain the optimal choice in the habit case.

Let consider equation (.2.8) in the caseK = 1:

Using the relation between state-price deators in separable and in habit markets: ζˆt =ζt(1 +ρ(t)), we get

⇔O1(t) =M(t)(1 +ρ(t))1−μμ . (.2.18) By using Itˆo's rule and (.2.18), we obtain

dO(t)

O(t) = [...]dt+

σM(t)+ (1

μ 1)(μ1 1)ρ(t) 1 +ρ(t) σρ(t)

dz. (.2.19) We can see that the percentage diusion process of O1(t)is

σO

1(t)=σM(t)+(1μ1)ρ(t)

1 +ρ(t) σρ(t). (.2.20) Inserting(.2.14), (.2.20) and (.1.5) into π in equation(2.5.2) we get

π(t) = (1−bρ(t)h(t)

w(t))[σM(t)+(1μ1)ρ(t)

1 +ρ(t)ρ(t)+ (1 + h(t)

w(t))(σ(t))−1φ(t) (.2.21) which gives equation (2.5.7) after reformulation.

.3 Symbol description

yx= dydx derivative of y with respect to x x the transpose of matrix x

x(t) =xt the value of process xat time t

x the optimal value of xrelated to dened optimization problem St the price process of risky assets

αi(·) the drift of a risky asset i σi(·) the volatility of a risky asset i zt standard Brownian motion

Et expectation given information available at time t P, Q probability measures

Ωprobability set rt riskless interest rate

λt the market price of risk process ζ(t)state-price density

ζˆ(t) the state price density in the habit case λt the market price of risk process

ΓTt the price at time t of a zero-coupon bond which pays a principal of one at time T

U(·) utility function V value function

υ subjective discount rate ct,0≤t≤T consumption ˆ

ct subsistence consumption dened in page 30 c consumption in a constrained problem Z(·)the bequest function

h(t) habit factor

a(t) andb(t)habit coecient

wt,0≤t≤T the value of wealth process at time t μ the degree of risk aversion

w0 initial wealth

I(·) inverse function of marginal utility

π proportional amount which agent invests to risky object L(·) a Lagrange function

y a Lagrange multiplier

q marginal cost of subsistence consumption per unit of standard of living ρ(t) process is dened in page 42

G(t) process is dened in page 44 φ(t)process is dened in page 49 O(t) process is dened in page 46

Other necessary denitions are in the text.

Bibliography

[1] BAIN, A and CRISAN, D (2009): Fundamentals of Stochastic Filtering, Springer, New York.

[2] CAMPBELL, J. Y. and COCHRANE J. H. (1999): By Force of Habit: A Consumption-Based Explanation of Aggregate Stock Market Behavior.

The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 107, No. 2, pp. 205-251.

[3] COCHRANE J. H (2005): Asset Pricing. Princeton University Press.

[4] CONSTANTINIDES G. M (1990): Habit Formation: A Resolution of the Equity Premium Puzzle. The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 98, No. 3, pp. 519-543.

[5] COX, J. C. and HUANG C-f. (1989). Optimal Consumption and Port-folio Policies when Asset Prices Follow a Diusion Process. Journal of Economic Theory 49, 33-83.

[6] COX, J. C. INGERSOLL, Jr., J. E and ROSS, S. A. (1985): A Theory of the Term Structure of Interest Rates. Econometrica 53(2), 385-407.

[7] DANA, R.-A. and JEANBLANC, M. (2003): Financial Markets in Con-tinuous Time. Springer-Verlag Heidelberg.

[8] DETEMPLE, J. B. and KARATZAS, I. (2003): Non-addictive Habits:

Optimal Consumption-portfolio policies. Journal of Economic Theory 113 265-285.

[9] DETEMPLE, J. B. and ZAPATERO, F. (1992): Optimal Consumption-Portfolio Policies with Habit Formation. Mathematical Finance 2(4), 251-274.

[10] DUFFIE, D. (2001): Dynamic Asset Pricing Theory, Princeton, NJ : Princeton University Press.

[11] DUFFIE, D. and L. G. EPSTEIN (1992a). Asset Pricing with Stochastic Dierential Utility. The Review of Financial Studies 5 (3), 411-436.

[12] DUFFIE, D. and L. G. EPSTEIN (1992b). Stochastic Dierential Util-ity. Econometrica 60 (2), 353-394.

[13] DUFFIE, D and SKIADAS, C(1994): Continuous-Time Security Pric-ing: A Utility Gradient Approach. Journal of Mathematical Economics, March 1994, 23, 107-132.

[14] DYNAN K. E. (2000):Habit Formation in Consumer Preferences: Evi-dence from Panel Data. The American Economic Review, Vol. 90, No.

3, pp. 391-4.

[15] EGGLEZOS, N. (2007): Aspects of Utility Maximization With Habit Formation: Dynamic Programming And Stochastic PDE's. Columbia University.

[16] EGGLEZOS, N. and KARATZAS, I. (2009): Utility Maximization With Habit Formation: Dynamic Programming and Stochastic PDE's. SIAM J. Control Optim., 48, 481- 520.

[17] FERSON, W. E. and G. M. Constantinides (1991): Habit Persistence and Durability in Aggregate Consumption," Journal of Financial Eco-nomics 29, 199-240.

[18] FRIEDMAN, a. (1964): Partial Dierential Equation of Parabolic Type.

Prentice-Hall, Englewood Clis, N.J.

[19] FUHRER, J.F. (2000): Habit Formation in Consumption and Its Impli-cations for Monetary-Policy Models. The American Economic Review, Vol. 90, No. 3 (Jun.,2000), pp. 367-390.

[20] GALI, J (1994): Keeping up with the Joneses: Consumption External-ities, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Prices. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 26, No. 1. (Feb., 1994), pp. 1-8.

[21] GOURINCHES, P-O. and PARKER J. A. (2002): Consumption over the Life Cycle. Econometrica , Vol. 70, No. 1 (Jan., 2002), pp. 47-89.

[22] HARRISON, J. M and KREPS, D. M.(1979): Martingales and Arbitrage in Multiperiod Securities Markets, Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 20, 381-408.

[23] HEATON, J. (1993): The Interaction Between Time-Nonseparable Pref-erences and Time Aggregation. Econometrica, Vol. 61, No. 2 , pp. 353-385.

[24] INGERSOLL, Jr., J. E. (1992): OptimalConsumption and Portfolio Rules with Intertemporally Dependent Utility of Consumption. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control16, 681-712.

[25] KARATZAS, I, LEHOCZKY, J.P. and SHREVE, S. E (1987): Optimal portfolio and consumption decisions for a Small Investor" on a nite horizon. SIAM Journalof Controland Optimization, Vol. 25, No. 6, November 1987.

KARATZAS, I, LEHOCZKY, J.P. SETHI, S. P and SHREVE, S. E (1986): Explicit Solution of a General Consumption/Investment Prob-lem. Mathematics of Operations ResearchVol. 11, No. 2, 1 May 1986.

[26] LAMBERTON, D and LAPEYRE, B (1996): Introduction to Stochastic Calculus Applied to Finance. Chapman & Hall.

[27] LANDIS, E. M. (1998): Second Order Equations of Elliptic and Parabolic Type. American Mathematic Society. Providence, Rhode Is-land.

[28] MEHRA, R. and PRESCOTT E. C. (1985): The Equity Premium: A Puzzle. J. Monetary Econ. 15 (March 1985): 145-161.

[29] MEHRA, R (2006): The Equity Premium Puzzle: A Review. In Foun-dations and Trends in Finance, Vol. 2, No. 1, 1-81.

[30] MERTON, R (1971): Optimum Consumption and Portfolio Rules in a Continuous-Time Model. Journal of Economic Theory 3, 373-413.

[31] MERTON, R (1990): Continuous-time Finance, Blackwell, Mas-sachusetts.

[32] MUNK, C (1997): Optimal Consumption/Portfolio Policies and Con-tingent Claims Pricing and Hedging in Incomplete Markets, Ph.D. dis-sertation,School of Business and Economics Odense University.

[33] MUNK, C (2008): Portfolio and Consumption Choice with Stochastic Investment Opportunities and Habit Formation in Preferences, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, vol. 32, issue 11, 3560-3589.

[34] MUNK, C and SØRENSEN, C (2004): Optimal Consumption and In-vestment Strategies with Stochastic Interest Rates. Journal of Banking

& Finance 28, 1987-2013.

[35] MUNK, C and SØORENSEN, C (2000): Optimal Consumption and Investment Strategies with Stochastic Interest Rates. WP 2000-9, De-partment of Finance, Copenhagen Business School. 1987-2013.

[36] MUNK, C and SØRENSEN, C (2005): Dynamic Asset Allocation with Stochastic Income and Interest Rates. Copenhagen Business School, Working Papers, Feb 2005.

[37] NAIK, N. Y and MOORE, M. J (1996): Habit Formation and Intertem-poral Substitution in Individual Food Consumption, Review of Eco-nomics and Statistics 78(2):321-28, May.

[38] ØKSENDAL, B. (1998): Stochastic Dierential Equations (Fifth ed.).

Springer-Verlag.

[39] PROTTER, D. (1999): A Partial Introduction to Finance. Working Paper, Department of Statistics, September 1999, Purdue University.

[40] REVUZ, D and Yor, M (1991): Continuous Martingales and Brownian Motion. New York, Springer.

[41] SALO, S(2000): Luentoja stokastisesta optimiohjauksesta ja sen sovel-luksista taloustieteissä. Helsingin kauppakorkeakoulun julkaisuja, HeSE print 2000.

[42] SCHRODER, M and SKIADAS, C (2002): An Isomorphism Between Asset Pricing Models With and Without Linear Habit Formation. The Review of Financial Sudies, Fall 2002 Vol. 15, No. 4, pp. 1189-1221.

[43] SCHRODER, M and SKIADAS, C (1999): Optimal Consumption and Portfolio Selection with Stochastic Dierential Utility. Journal of Eco-nomic Theory 89, pp. 68-126.

[44] Stochastic Economic Dynamics, edited by Bjarne S. Jensen and Tapio Palokangas, CBS Press 2007.

[45] SUNDARESAN, S. M. (1989): Intertemporally Dependent Preferences and the Volatility of Consumption and Wealth. The Review of Financial Studies , Vol. 2, No. 1, p. 73-89.

[46] WISMER, D. A. and CHATTERGY, R. (1978): Introduction to nonlin-ear optimization : a problem solving approach . Elsevier North-Holland, Inc.

Chapter 3

Monte Carlo Computation of Optimal Portfolio Choice with Habit Formation

Abstract

This paper studies optimal consumption and portfolio choice of an investor with habit formation in preferences. The Monte Carlo co-variation (MCC) method is used for optimal portfolio selection when an investor's preferences are time-separable. This paper works on the MCC method so that it is applicable to the case of more general utili-ties. As an example,I solve the optimal portfolio problem in the case where the interest rate adheres to Cox-Ingersoll-Ross dynamics and stock prices are mean reverting using the method and compare my results to the time-separable case.

3.1 Introduction

Time separability of consumption utilities is a common assumption in the theory of nancial economics. Various empirical studies suggest that there are problems with this assumption. Sometimes these problems are solvable by applying a more general utility formulation.

Applying time separable utilities, rational expectation models often gen-erate results that are empirically valid only if we assume a very risk-averse investor. If the risk aversion coecient is plausible, then the representative investor in the models puts much more money in the risky investment than has been observed empirically. Between 1889-2005, the average return on equity in the U.S stock market was seven percent and the average yield on short-term debt was less than one percent. Mehra and Precott (1985) and Mehra (2006) show that the common general equilibrium model with separa-ble utilities cannot explain why the rst rate is so low and the second rate is so high. That so-called equity premium puzzle is solvable using a more gen-eral form of the utility function. In this paper, I reject the time-separability assumption and assume that an agent's utilities adhere to a more general function, the habit utility function.

Merton (1971) examines the continuous-time consumption-portfolio prob-lem for an individual whose income is generated by capital gains on invest-ments in assets with prices that satisfy geometric Brownian motion. For the solution of an individual's optimization problem, Merton uses Itô's lemma and stochastic analysis. A few papers have studied the consumption and investment problem of an agent with habit utilities either in the general equilibrium or in the partial equilibrium model (e.g. Sundaresan (1989), Constantinides (1990), Ingersoll (1992), Munk (2008)).

Constantinides (1990) and Sundaresan (1989) present a solution to the equity premium puzzle by applying habit utilities. Constantidines's (1990) reason for including habit function in preferences form is simply to nd a the-oretical model that can explain the equity premium puzzle. In the literature, an intuitive interpretation is also given for the habit utility function. There

are temporal dependencies in the sense that utility in period t depends not just on consumption in the same period but also on the level of consumption in previous periods. An individual who consumes a lot in period (t-1) will get used to that high level of consumption, and will more strongly desire consumption in period t (Kocherlakota (1996)).

If the assumption of time separability is rejected, two types of eects are possible: intertemporal substitution or intertemporal complementarity.

In the case of intertemporal substitutes a consumer buys a durable good in period t, but receives the utility of this good in periods t+i, i > 0 without spending any money.

Ferson and Constantinides (1991) empirically study habit persistence in preferences and the durability of consumption goods which both imply time-nonseparability of the derived utility for consumption expenditures. They investigate which eect dominates and nd evidence in monthly, quarterly and annual data that habit persistence dominates over durability. Obviously, nondurables are more habit" than durables. Detemple and Zapatero (1992) and Egglezos (2007) solve the optimal consumption when an investor has habit utilities, but they do not nd an exact solution for an optimal portfolio choice.

Munk (2008) nds a closed-form solution to the optimal consumption and portfolio choice with habit utilities and mean-reverting stock returns.

He also solves numerically the problem in the habit case when the interest rate is stochastic and stock prices are mean-reverting. Munk uses a Monte Carlo simulation to solve the relevant partial dierential equation.

Cvitanic et al. (2003) propose a numerical method for an optimal port-folio choice in the case where the interest rate follows Cox-Ingersoll-Ross dynamics and the stock prices are mean-reverting. This is a very exible method and, by exploiting it, it is possible to solve the optimal portfolio problem in the habit case, making dierent assumptions about nancial as-sets. The only requirements are that markets have to be complete and the expanded opportunity set has to be Markovian, i.e. all parameters of

mar-ket processes depend on the n-dimensional Brownian motion process which describes uncertainty in the economy. In this paper, I extend this method to the problem of an investor with habit utilities.

The rest of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 gives some set-ups and denes utilities. Sections 3 and 4 present the assumptions related to nancial markets and dene a precise optimization problem. Section 5 shows how to nd the optimal consumption in the case of habit utilities by using the martingale method solution. Section 6 presents the extension of Cvitanic's (2003) Monte Carlo covariation method in the habit case. Section 7 shows the results for the optimal portfolio choice problem and nally, section 8 concludes.