• Ei tuloksia

Cost of Private Finance Relative to Total Cost of Public Finance

In document PUBLIC-PRIVATE PARTNERSHIP (sivua 150-153)

7 RESULTS

7.2 Cost of Private Finance Relative to Total Cost of Public Finance

However, the private company has a much higher incentive to exert effort on cost savings than increasing the benefits the asset delivers, because it gains only a fraction of the effort it gives to improving the service;

whereas it captures all the yields from cost saving efforts – the government

“profit” is independent of the costs. The concession ensures efficiency, but unless the revenue mechanism is tied to the private costs, the contract favors the project company, and equitability is not secured in the long-run.

Within the limits of the model developed it also possible to infer that the private company assumes all production risks related to general macroeconomic conditions and input and prices unique to the particular infrastructure asset, or more accurately, the financiers of the private company assume the risks, which is reasonable, given that they are also entitled to all the surplus yields from cost savings. More risk is generally acceptable with a higher expected return. In the traditional path of procurement, taxpayers, who effectively provide the funds as well as credit insurance to the sovereign state, are not remunerated for the risks they assume.

7.2 Cost of Private Finance Relative to Total Cost of Public Finance

Most importantly, the government does not consider the implicit costs, which are a basic, but fundamental concept in economic theory. Given that the government has access to cheap capital it could have chosen to use the resources by investing in an efficient portfolio of assets, which provide an expected rate of return higher than the risk-free rate. By choosing to forego this opportunity, the government in fact loses a lucrative opportunity to make an investment profit.

To review, opportunity cost is the value of the best alternative use of resources, in this case pure capital. One course of action the government could follow instead of investing itself in the infrastructure project is pure financial investment. The government, in essence, would function like any bank, taking in funds amounting to D, for which it pays an interest rate rf,, denoted by (1), and subsequently investing these resources I = D in an efficient portfolio of assets that generate an expected rate of return rp > rf,. The government would thus be expecting revenues of R = I(rp) each year, debt service costs of I(rf) each year, and making an expected investment profit of πi = I(rp – rf) each year.

The government, in considering functioning like a bank, should be willing to invest in the project if it is offered the same rate of return rd that other debt investors expect from this venture, considering all the risks inherent in the project projections. Therefore, the government should be indifferent between investing in some other portfolio of assets and investing in the project, if rp = rd.139 This is essentially equal to the government investing in the project at a fair cost of capital. And the periodic opportunity cost of investing itself in the project, and not in a portfolio of assets, is equal to the revenue foregone, OC = I(rd). Moreover, the total OC over the life of the project is the cumulative total of periodic opportunity costs I(rd)^T.

The government, by investing itself in the project, thus foregoes the opportunity of receiving revenues of I(rd). Its periodic explicit debt service costs are, given an excellent credit rating, still defined by the risk-free rate

139 The rate rd is essentially also the rate at which the private supplier can raise capital.

rf of borrowing, and amount to only I(rf). However, the opportunity cost calculated includes both the explicit and implicit costs, and therefore the periodic implicit costs of investing in the infrastructure project are defined by I(rd) – I(rf) = I(rd – rf), where rd > rf,, because the project is inherently risky. The total implicit costs of the government investing in the project are thus defined by I(rd – rf)^T, and are essentially equal to the customary conception of differences in private and public sector cost of capital.

These implicit, economic costs are typically ignored in PPP analysis, and explain – moreover quantifies – the apparent, but erroneous cheapness of sovereign funding.

What happens from the perspective of the private party is that the government intervenes in the construction market and favors the public party by supplying it with unnaturally cheap capital, which in the case of a capital-intensive infrastructure project represents a key production factor and a decisive competitive advantage, and equal to the government’s implicit costs, I(rd – rf)^T. This is nothing else than a form of subvention, which, in fact, is prohibited by competitive legislation.

Economic theory attests that it is beneficial for a social planner, i.e. the government, to ensure that certain public goods such as highways are provided, but economic theory also promotes fair competition and that for any given purpose the most efficient means are chosen. There is no reason why a government should favor a public party over a private party when alternatives are available, and the government is effectively violating sound economic principles captured in legislation as well. The government could, in principle, borrow on its general credit and leak the funds at the same cost of capital to the private party, which would ensure a fair competitive setting.

To illustrate the rationale of the result further, the implications of a counter-assumption were explored. More specifically, an extreme example of financing all economic activity on a general government rating was used. Should this occur, the international financial markets would

eventually realize the actual risk inherent in the governments deteriorating loan portfolio, which would obviously include some very risky ventures (stimulated, partly, by cheap capital), lower the general credit rating of the nation as a consequence, and thereby correct the pricing of capital inevitably. Thus, by the logic of induction, because the practice is undesirable if extended indefinitely, it follows that the practice must be undesirable for a singular case too.

By confusing its role as a social planner and a producer unit, the government distorts the functioning of markets. A public option may not be economically the most low-cost alternative, but it is nevertheless chosen when low-cost capital offsets higher production costs. A government cannot, by borrowing and investing itself in the project benefit the domestic economy, because it could achieve the same effect by adopting the role of a pure investor and letting the project company raise funds at a fair cost of capital. Therefore, to evaluate a public and private led production on a level fair basis, the government should, itself, finance on a project basis, or allow the private party access to the low-cost funds available on the government’s credit rating. However, even this approach would fail to account for differences in transaction costs between a PPP and a traditional government led approach.

7.3 Comparative Economic Efficiency of Public-Private Partnership

In document PUBLIC-PRIVATE PARTNERSHIP (sivua 150-153)