• Ei tuloksia

Quality Competition and Social Welfare in Markets with Partial Coverage : New Results

N/A
N/A
Info
Lataa
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Jaa "Quality Competition and Social Welfare in Markets with Partial Coverage : New Results"

Copied!
24
0
0

Kokoteksti

(1)

Discussion Papers

Quality Competition and Social Welfare in Markets with Partial Coverage: New Results

Gregory S. Amacher

Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University and

Erkki Koskela

University of Helsinki, RUESG and HECER and

Markku Ollikainen University of Helsinki

Discussion Paper No. 69 June 2005

ISSN 1795-0562

HECER – Helsinki Center of Economic Research, P.O. Box 17 (Arkadiankatu 7), FI-00014 University of Helsinki, FINLAND, Tel +358-9-191-28780, Fax +358-9-191-28781, E-mail info-hecer@helsinki.fi, Internetwww.hecer.fi

(2)

Quality Competition and Social Welfare in Markets with Partial Coverage: New Results*

Abstract

We use a vertical product differentiation model under partial market coverage to study the social welfare optimum and duopoly equilibrium when convex costs of quality provision are either fixed or variable in terms of production. We show the following new results. First, under fixed costs the social planner charges a uniform price for the single variant that just covers costs of quality provision. Like the duopoly equilibrium, this socially optimal pricing entails a partially uncovered market, but a smaller share of the market is served compared to the duopoly equilibrium. Second, for the variable cost case, it is socially optimal to provide both high and low quality variants, but market shares need not be equal. This differs from the result in fully covered markets. Third, in the duopoly equilibrium, the quality spread is too wide under variable costs relative to the social optimum. Under fixed costs the duopoly produces two variants, but quality is too low relative to the social optimum, which has only one variant.

JEL Classification: L13, D60.

Keywords: Product differentiation, partial market coverage, social welfare.

Gregory S. Amacher Erkki Koskela

College of Natural Resources Department of Economics

304 D Cheatham Hall P.O. Box 17 (Arkadiankatu 7)

Virginia Polytechnic Institute and University of Helsinki

State University FI-00014 University of Helsinki

Blacksburg, VA 24601 FINLAND

USA e-mail:erkki.koskela@helsinki.fi

e-mail:gamacher@vt.edu Markku Ollikainen

Department of Economics and Management P.O. Box 27

FI-00014 University of Helsinki FINLAND

e-mail:markku.ollikainen@helsinki.fi

* The authors thank two anonymous referees for valuable comments on an earlier version, professor Luca Lambertini for useful discussions, and Dr. Chiara Lombardini- Riipinen for computational help and comments. Koskela thanks the Research Unit of Economic Structures and Growth (RUESG) at the University of Helsinki for financial support. Ollikainen thanks the Academy of Finland (the grant No. 204476) for the position of Senior Researcher Fellow.

(3)

A well-established result in vertical product differentiation models is that a duopoly consisting of high and low quality firms leads to product quality dispersion that is too high and average levels of quality that are too low relative to the socially optimal outcome (see Crampes and Hollander 1995). This result has been established under the assumption that markets are fully covered, i.e., that all consumers purchase positive quantities of the good in question. A consequence of full market coverage is that, even though duopoly qualities differ from the socially optimal ones, the quantities produced by the firms are always equivalent.

When the market is partially covered the nature of duopoly equilibrium depends on whether the costs of production are fixed or variable.1 In both cases, however, if the duopoly and socially optimal outcomes differ, then not only the qualities but also the quantities will differ across outcomes. The direction of these differences is not clear, because in the literature on partial market coverage the socially optimal outcome has remained an open issue. Our work fills an important gap concerning the socially optimum. We characterize the properties of socially optimal qualities and solve for the divergence between duopoly and social outcomes when a market is partially covered.

Unlike other work, we analyze and compare both cases of fixed and variable costs.2

1 In the vertical product differentiation literature, “fixed costs” refer to zero marginal and average costs of producing the product itself, but positive and convex costs of providing productquality. Term “variable cost” in turn refers to the case where production has constant average and marginal costs, butquality provision has positive and convex costs.

2 Under the assumption of fixed costs, Ronnen (1991) considers minimum quality standards without analyzing socially optimal quality provision. Lambertini (1996), in turn, considers the

(4)

Our main objective is to compare socially optimal qualities and quantities with the duopoly solution. Thus, we take for granted that there exists a duopoly equilibrium exhibiting partial coverage. Shaked and Sutton (1982, 1983) were the first to provide sufficient conditions for a market equilibrium with at most two firms providing distinct qualities and enjoying positive profits. Wauthy (1996) further showed that the distribution of consumers and endogenous quality choices determine if the market is partially or completely served. Acharyya (1998) focused on the problem of a monopoly providing one or two variants of a good.

When analyzing socially optimal outcomes under variable costs, we characterize the social optimum in the same way that Crampes and Hollander (1995) did for the fully covered market case. For fixed costs we follow Ecchia et al. (2002), who showed that it is optimal to provide just one quality level; however, they did not study the problem of socially optimal price setting, nor did they analyze how the fixed cost case may differ from the variable cost case. Like other work, our duopoly outcome is solved as the subgame perfect equilibrium of a two-stage game. Firms maximize profits by first competing in qualities and then competing in prices.

Our characterization of the socially optimal outcome provides several new findings. First, under fixed costs, the social planner should provide one quality variant and charge a uniform price that just covers the costs of quality provision. The social optimum entails the market being partially covered, and less of the market is covered compared to the duopoly equilibrium with two quality variants. Second, under variable variable cost case but does not examine the socially optimal outcome. Motta (1993) allows for both variable and fixed costs with partial market coverage but does not explicitly solve for the socially optimal outcome. Instead he uses numerical illustrations to compare consumer surplus in the different equilibria.

(5)

costs, both quality variants are socially optimal, but unlike with fully covered markets their market shares need not to be equal. Third, we find that the quality spread in the duopoly equilibrium is too wide under variable costs. Under fixed costs, a duopoly produces two variants with too low quality relative to the one socially optimal variant.

We proceed as follows. Section 2 presents a basic duopoly model and the profit maximizing solution with partial market coverage for both fixed and variable costs of production. In Section 3 we compare the socially optimal and profit-maximizing qualities. Finally, we provide a brief conclusion.

2. A Duopoly Model of Vertical Product Differentiation with Partial Market Coverage

Under an assumption of partial market coverage, each consumer is typically assumed to purchase either one unit of a good or nothing. Let a consumer have a utility function u (see e.g. Tirole 1988, pp 96-97, 296-298),

k

k p

s

u=θ − , (1)

where sk and pk are the quality and price of the kth good.3 In (1), θ represents the consumer’s taste parameter, so that the consumer derives a surplus equal to θ skpk from a good of quality skand pricepk. Suppose there are two possible qualities of goods produced by two types of firms, k = H (high quality) and k = L (low quality). Consumers’

(6)

taste parameters are assumed to be uniformly distributed over qualities on a definite interval, θ

[ ]

θ,θ , withθ θ =1 (see e.g. Motta 1993, or Cremer and Thisse 1999).

We assume that the high and low quality firms have quadratic and convex cost functions for providing quality,

L H bs

s

ck k k fork ,

2 ) 1

( = 2 = . (2)

Because consumers can purchase either one unit or nothing of each good, the consumer who is indifferent between the high and low quality goods has a threshold taste parameter defined by

L H

L H

s s

p p

= −

θˆ . Under partial market coverage, some consumers do not enter

the market. Here,the lowest marginal willingness to pay parameter value can be defined for the consumer who is indifferent between buying and not buying the good, i.e.,

L c L

s

= p

θ . Partial market coverage additionally requires that

L L

s

< p

θ . Under the uniform

distribution for the taste parameter, demands for high and low quality products become θ

θ − ˆ

H =

q and qL =θˆ−θc, where qH and qL are the number of consumers purchasing from the low and high quality firm, respectively.

Based on the above assumptions, we will focus on cases where the costs of providing quality are either fixed or variable with respect to production. The fixed cost case might be interpreted as a situation where firms engage in R&D activities to improve quality. Kuhn (2000) argued that the variable cost case might be more realistic than the

3Throughout the paper, derivatives of functions with one argument will be denoted by primes, while partial derivatives will be denoted by subscripts of functions with many arguments.

(7)

fixed cost case, because it avoids an implausible feature of fixed costs. This is that the high quality firm has both higher profits and a larger market share in equilibrium.4 In conformity with observations from practice, our variable cost case results in an equilibrium where the profits of the high quality firm are higher than those of the low quality firm. However, the market share of the high quality firm is lower than that of the low quality firm.

2.1 Price and Quality Games: Fixed costs

An analysis of duopoly competition under fixed costs of production was originally provided by Ronnen (1991) and further analyzed by Wauthy (1998). We first briefly develop some features of this model. When the cost of quality provision is fixed in terms of quantity produced, then given the demands qkand the cost function in (2), the profit functions of the high and low quality firm are:

) ( k

k k k

k = p qc s

π ,for k =H,L. (3)

Playing a two-stage game, the firms maximize their profits by competing first in qualities (stage 1) and then competing in prices (stage 2). Firms are assumed to move

4 This result was originally discovered by Lehmann-Grube (1997). He also showed that it holds irrespective of whether the firms choose their qualities simultaneously or sequentially.

(8)

simultaneously in each stage.5 We can solve for the subgame perfect equilibrium of this game. This equilibrium relies, as usual, on commitment by firms in terms of quality.

In the second stage, firms choose prices given the costs of quality production.

From the first-order conditions of (3), ∂ ∂ H =0

H p

π and ∂ ∂ L =0

L p

π , we can solve for the optimal prices and their difference as follows,

L H

L H H

H s s

s s p s

= −

4

) (

2 θ

;

L H

L H L

L s s

s s p s

= −

4

)

( θ

;

L H

L H L H L

H s s

s s s p s

p

= −

− 4

) )(

2

* (

* θ

(4)

Thus, duopoly prices depend on quality differences and the upper bound of the consumer taste distribution. The lower bound of the taste distribution does not matter here, because in partially covered markets the lowest critical value of marginal willingness to pay is endogenous.

Inserting the above prices into the respective profit functions yields the indirect profit functions for each firm’s choice of quality,

2 2

2 2

2 1 ) 4

(

) (

4

H L

H L H H

H bs

s s

s s

s

+

= −

θ

π ; 2 2 2

2 1 ) 4

(

) (

L L

H L L H H

L bs

s s

s s s

s

+

= −

θ

π . (5)

Differentiating equations in (5) with respect to qualities gives,

5 Lambertini (1996) has shown that the simultaneous move game is the only pure strategy equilibrium possible for a partial market coverage model with variable costs of producing quality.

(9)

) 0 4

(

) (

8 4

) 4

(

) (

32

2 2 2 2 3

2

2 − =

+

− + +

+

= −

H L

H

L H H H

L H

L H H H

H bs

s s

s s s s

s s

s s s s

θ θ

θ

π (6a)

) 0 4

(

) (

) 4

(

) (

2

2 2 2

3

2 − =

+

− + −

+

= −

L L

H

L H L

H H L

H

L H L H L

L bs

s s

s s s

s s s

s

s s s s s

θ θ

θ

π (6b)

Solving these first-order conditions for high and low quality and their difference with Mathematica yields,

sH b

253311 2

.

0 θ

=

;sL b

0482383 2

.

0 θ

=

;sH sL b

2050727 2

.

0 θ

=

. (7)

Thus, equilibrium duopoly qualities and the quality difference between firms depend positively on the square of the upper bound of taste distribution, θ 2, and negatively on the marginal cost parameter of quality provision,b.

Using these optimal qualities, we can now solve for the prices and demands of both quality variants as a function of exogenous parameters:

pH b

107662 3

.

0 θ

=

;

pL b

010251 3

.

0 θ

=

; qH =0.524994θ ; qL =0.262497θ . The addition of demands, which indicates the resulting coverage in the market, is therefore given by

θ 787491 .

=0 +

L

H q

q .6 If for the moment we normalize θ =1 (and θ =0), then we can directly conclude that about 79% of consumers enter the market and buy one of the two quality variants. Because the high quality firm charges a higher price and faces a larger demand, it has higher profits and greater market share than the low quality firm. This can

6It is easy to verify that our results fulfill conditions A and A’ for partial market coverage under zero costs of quality provision proved in Wauhty (1996).

(10)

also be seen from the profit solutions for high and low quality firms, i.e.,

H b

0244386 4

.

0 θ

π = and

L b

00152741 4

.

0 θ

π = . In the next section we show that this result must be modified for the case of variable costs of production.

2.2 Price and Quality Games: Variable costs

Now we assume that the costs of providing quality are variable in terms of production (see e.g. Motta 1993 and Lehmann-Grube 1997). Under this assumption, and given demands qk and the cost function in (2), the profit functions for each firm are written,

[

k k k

]

k

k = pc (s )q

π , for k =H,L. (8)

As before, in the second stage firms choose prices given the costs of quality production.

From the first-order conditions, ∂ ∂ H =0

H p

π and ∂ ∂ L =0

L p

π , we can solve for the following optimal prices,

[ ]

L H

L H

H L

H H

H s s

s s

bs s s p s

+ +

= −

4

) ) 2 / 1 ( ( )

(

2 2

(9a)

[ ]

L H

L H H

L H L

L s s

s s bs

s s p s

+ +

= −

4

) )

2 / 1 ((

)

( 2 2

θ . (9b)

L H

L H H L

H L H L

H s s

s s bs s

s s p s

p

− +

= −

− 4

) (

) 2 / 1 ( ) )(

2

( 2 2

*

* θ

(9c)

(11)

Again, duopoly prices and their difference depend on quality differences and on the upper bound of the consumer taste distribution.

Substituting these optimal prices into the profit functions, indirect profits in terms of quality can be expressed as,

[ ]

2 2 2

2 2 2

) 4

( 4

) 2

( 4 ) (

L H

L H L

H H

H s s

s s b s

s s

+

+ +

= −

θ

π (10a)

[ ]

2 2 2

2

*

) 4

( 4

) (

2 ) (

L H

L H L

H H L

L s s

s s b s

s s s

+

− +

= − θ

π . (10b)

Optimal second stage qualities then follow from the first-order conditions,

[ ]

0

) 4

( 4

) 2 5

22 24

( ) 2 3

4 (

0 4 3

3 2 2

3 2

2 2

− =

− +

− +

⇔ Ω

∂ =

L H

L L H L H H

L L H H H

H

s s

s s s s s s

b s s s s s

θ

π (11a)

[ ]

0

) 4

( 4

) 2 15

4 )(

( ) 7 4 (

0 2 3

2 2

2

− =

+

− +

⇔ Λ

∂ =

L H

L L H H

L H L

H H L

L

s s

s s s s

s s b s s s s

θ

π , (11b)

where Ω=sH

[

4θ +b(2sH +sL)

]

and Λ=sH

[

2θ 2 +b(sH +sL)

]

.

Given the complexity of the first-order conditions, solving for the actual equilibrium qualities is a bit laborious. Without loss of generality we define sH =dsL for some d >1, where dindicates the degree of product differentiation between firms expressed in terms of the quality spread between high and low quality firms. Note that this assumption does not predetermine the results presented later concerning differences between socially optimal and duopoly outcomes.

(12)

Using sH =dsLand solving (11a) - (11b) with Mathematica, we obtain the following equilibrium qualities and their difference,

sH b

8195 2

.

0 θ

=

; sL b

3987 2

.

0 θ

=

, sH sL b

4208 2

.

0 θ

=

. (12)

The equilibrium duopoly qualities and the degree of quality differentiation are positive functions of the upper bound of the square of the taste distribution, θ 2, and a negative function of the marginal cost parameter of quality provision,b. This result is qualitatively similar to that found in full market coverage models.

Note also that the quality difference is higher with variable costs compared to the fixed cost case. This can be interpreted as follows. Under fixed costs, the costs of producing both quality variants of the good in the second stage are zero (even though the costs of providing quality differ). Under variable costs the costs of providing both quality variants in the second stage are strictly positive. Thus under variable costs of production, quality competition between the firms is tighter, because the firms obtain greater rents from differentiating compared to the fixed cost case.

Finally, using the optimal qualities above, we can solve the previous first-order conditions for equilibrium prices and demands to obtain

pH b

453313 2

.

0 θ

=

;

pL b

15002 2

.

0 θ

=

; qH =0.279245θ ; qL =0.344503θ . The firms’ indirect profit

functions can now be solved to obtain

b

H

0328129 3

.

~ 0 θ

π = ;

b

L

024298 3

.

~ 0 θ

π = .

Interestingly, for the case of variable costs of production, the high quality firm has higher

(13)

profits but lower market share than the low quality firm. The overall demand (coverage) in the market is given by qH +qL=0.623748θ . Thus, under variable costs, overall market coverage is smaller than in the case of fixed costs. This is a natural result since production costs are now positive and the quality spread is wider, which serves to relax price competition between firms and allows them to charge higher prices.

3. Socially Optimal versus Profit-Maximizing Quality Decisions

Now we turn to the determination of socially optimal qualities and the relationship of these with equilibrium duopoly qualities, under both assumptions of fixed and variable costs of production. The socially optimal qualities are those that maximize a social welfare function, defined as the sum of consumers’ and producers’ surplus,

L H L

H CS

CS

SW = + +π +π .

3.1 Fixed Costs and the Socially Optimal Qualities

We start by analyzing the properties of the first-best solution under fixed costs. Noting that the good is produced at zero marginal cost yields the following social welfare function,

L H L

Hd s d c c

s SW

c

− +

=

θ θ

θθ θ

θ θ

θ

ˆ

ˆ

. (13)

(14)

where we have used θ θ θ

θ

d p s

CSH ( H H)

ˆ

=

, θ θ θ

θ

d p s

CSL L L

c

) (

ˆ

=

,

H H

H =

p dθc

π θ

θˆ

, and L pLd cL

c

=

θ

π θ

θ ˆ

, with 2

2 1

H

H bs

c = and 2

2 1

L

L bs

c = from (2).

In (13), the integrals indicate the size of demand for both variants. As the costs of producing quality are lump sum in this case, they are independent of the size of demand.

The social planner simultaneously chooses prices and qualities to maximize (13).

The planner accounts for the critical taste parameter separating consumers of high and low quality variants, while keeping it open whether it is socially optimal to serve the whole market or not. Thus, the planner uses the following critical values of the taste parameter,

L H

L H

s s

p p

= −

θˆ ; θc =θ. (14)

Using (14) and differentiating first the social welfare function (13) with respect to high and low quality prices gives pH = pL.7 Inserting this into the social welfare function and differentiating it with respect to high and low qualities yields,

0 ) 2 2(

1 2 − =

= H

s bs

SWH θ , ( 2 ) 0

2

1 − 2 − =

= L

s bs

SWL θ . (15)

7 The first-order conditions for the prices of the high and low variants are

=0 + −

− −

=

L H

L L

H H

p s s

p s

s SW p

H , =0

− −

= −

L H

L L

H H

p s s

p s

s SW p

L .

(15)

Solving for optimal high quality gives sHw b

2 θ2

= . Note however that SWsL <0, implying

production of the low quality variant is zero. Thus, it is socially optimal to provide just one quality variant (high quality),

sw b 2 θ2

= , as pointed out by Ecchia et al. (2002).

We can compare the socially optimal solution and the duopoly in two ways, by relating high and average qualities in the duopoly equilibrium to the quality of the single socially optimal variant. Average quality can be solved with the help of (7) and related demands, which gives

sa b

2

* = 0.184953θ

. For the quality difference we obtain,

246689 0 .

0 2

* − =− <

s b

sH w θ

(16)

Hence, a duopoly provides both too little high and average quality relative to the socially optimal solution. This implies profit maximization results in quality dispersion that is socially suboptimal, and even the level of high quality provided is lower than the quality of the single socially optimal variant.We summarize these findings in:

Proposition 1. Under fixed costs of production, the socially optimal outcome involves

production of only the high quality variant. Compared to the socially optimal outcome, the profit maximizing duopoly provides two variants, and even the high quality provided by the duopoly is lower than that of the single socially optimal variant.

Using the socially optimal qualities, we can also solve for socially optimal prices.

Inserting the optimal qualities above into the first-order conditions for prices implies that

(16)

the optimal price is zero, because for the given quality and its costs, the cost of production is zero. This cannot, however, be optimal in the long run, as costs of providing quality would remain unpaid. Therefore, we use a pricing rule consistent with the principle of long run optimality, which requires that not only variable but also fixed costs to be paid.8 Drawing on this principle, we next examine optimal price setting for the socially optimal single variant, focusing on consequences for covering the market.

Intuition suggests that the costs of quality provision and the consumer taste distribution will jointly define if the market becomes covered or not. More specifically, we demonstrate

Proposition 2. Under fixed costs of production, the social planner (i) provides one quality variant and charges a uniform price that just covers the costs of quality provision, (ii) serves half of the market, and less than the duopoly, if the original duopoly equilibrium only partially covers the market,and (iii)a general condition for the market to become fully covered given a taste distribution θ −θ =1 is thatθ ≥2.

Proof:

Part (ii). Define the critical consumer just buying the good by θc ≥θ . The price which just covers the costs of the single variant is pw4/8b(θ−θc). Using this price in the indifference relation, θcswpw =0, the value of the critical taste parameter is

2 θ /

θc = . The market will be partially covered if θ <θc and fully covered if θ ≥θc. Recalling that θ −θ =1, the latter condition can be re-expressed as θ ≥2. Finally, for duopoly equilibrium we have as the critical taste parameter, θc =0.2θ , which is less than above. Thus, the market is uncovered.

8 This principle is similar to a reasonable requirement that in the long run a social planner must run a balanced budget.

(17)

Part (i). Suppose now that the planner charges a price p′> pW. Under higher price the indifference relation, θ′swp′=0, implies θ′>θc. Then, SW(pw)−SW(p′)>0, indicating that charging higher price reduces social welfare (see Appendix). Suppose next that the planner charges a price p′′< pW. Then the fixed costs of serving the market would not be gathered, which contradicts the long run optimality condition. Q.E.D.

Proposition 2 is new in the literature. It demonstrates that the socially optimal pricing strategy implies partial coverage if the duopoly equilibrium serves only part of the market. We contrast the properties of the social optimum and the duopoly equilibrium for the fixed cost case in Table 1.

Table 1.Duopoly and Social optimum in the fixed cost case

Duopoly equilibrium Social optimum θ

θc =0.2 θc =0.5θ b

sH =0.253311θ 2/ b

sL =0.0482383θ 2/ sw =0.5θ 2/b b

pH =0.107662θ 3/ b

pL =0.010251θ 2/ pw =0.25θ3/b θ

787491 .

=0 +

L

H q

q qw =0.5θ

Interestingly, the socially optimal price is higher than the price of the high quality variant in the duopoly equilibrium. This naturally follows for two reasons: the absence of differentiation and the higher quality of the product in the social optimum. Consequently, a smaller share of the market becomes served, as indicated by the last row of Table 1.

Hence, the duopoly equilibrium and the social optimum differ in many respects.

(18)

3.2 Variable Costs and the Socially Optimal Qualities

Next we compare the duopoly solution with the socially optimal one under variable costs of production. Summing up consumers’ and producers’ surplus and recognizing that, unlike with fixed costs of production, the assumption of variable production costs allows the social welfare maximizer to offer products at a nonzero marginal cost, we obtain the following social welfare function (see Crampes and Hollander 1995 and Lambertini 1996),

θ θ

θ

θ θ

θ θ

θ

d c s d

c s

SW H H L L

c

) (

) (

ˆ

ˆ

− +

=

∫ ∫

. (13’)

For the variable cost case, CSH , CSL , cH , and cL are as defined before, but we have

now used π θ θ

θ

d c pH H

H ( )

ˆ

= , and π θ θ

θ

d c p

c

L L

L ( )

ˆ

= . We will also replace the

duopoly prices by the marginal costs of quality provision in the definition of the critical taste parameters θˆ and θc. Hence, in (13’), the new threshold critical taste parameters for the upper and lower bounds of the taste distribution (derived from the conventional indifference relations) become,

) 2 (

ˆ 1

L

H s

s

b +

θ = ; C bsL

2

= 1

θ . (20)

(19)

Using (20) and differentiating the social welfare function (13’) with respect to the qualities sH and sL then gives the following first-order conditions,



 

 −

=

 

 −

= H H

s bs bs

SWH θ θ θ θˆ

2 ˆ 0 2

2 2

, (21a)





 −

=

 

 −

= L

C C L

s bs bs

SWL θ θ θ θ

2 ˆ

2 ˆ 0

2 2

. (21b)

The socially optimal qualities can then be solved from (21a) and (21b) to obtain,

sHw b 5 4θ2

= ,

swL b 5 2θ2

= and

s b sHw Lw

5 2θ2

=

− . (22)

Like the quality difference in the profit maximizing duopoly case, the socially optimal quality difference depends positively on the square upper bound of the taste distribution, θ 2 and negatively on the marginal cost parameter of quality provisionb.

To study the relationship between socially optimal qualities in the duopoly and social welfare maximization outcomes, we obtain (using equation 12),

0195 0 .

0 2

* − = >

s b

sH Hw θ

, (23a)

087 0 .

0 2

* − =− <

s b

sL wL θ

. (23b)

The magnitude of these expressions also depends on the size of the squared upper bound of the taste distribution, which indicates how many consumers can potentially be captured by differentiating product qualities. In contrast to the fixed cost case, the profit-

(20)

maximizing duopoly produces too much of the high quality variant and too little of the low quality variant than would the social planner. Equations (23a) and (23b) indicate that profit maximization gives a quality dispersion that is too wide. In other words, in order to relax price competition, firms will behave in a manner that increases the spread of quality dispersion in order to maximize profits. This behavior decreases social welfare.

Next, we solve for the quality demands under the socially optimal outcome. Using (22) in (20) and the definition of demands yields qHw =θ(1−0.6θ) and qLw =0.4θ 2. From the assumptions that θ −θ =1 and

L L

s

< p

θ , partial coverage requires that θ ≤1.3,

which is consistent with the solutions above. Thus, generally, the market shares for the high and low quality firms will differ and depend on the size of the upper bound of the taste distribution θ . The market shares will be equal only in two special cases: θ =1, or

666667 .

=0

θ . Assuming for the moment that θ =1 so that θ =0, the difference between total demand in the socially optimal and duopoly outcomes is:

0 176252 .

0 ) (

)

( + − H + L = >

w L w

H q q q

q . This implies that production of each variant and

market coverage are both too small under the duopoly. We summarize these findings in:

Proposition 3. Under variable costs of production, the socially optimal outcome involves

provision of both high and low quality variants. Unlike in the case of a fully covered market, the market shares of high and low quality variants need not to be equal.

Compared to the socially optimal outcome, the profit maximizing duopoly provides too much high quality and too little low quality.

(21)

Intuitively, when the cost of production is variable, price competition, which leads to increased production, is costly for the firms. To avoid “excessive” price competition the duopolists restrict production in order to charge prices higher than marginal production costs. This broadens differentiation between the two variants, because differentiation is crucial for increasing market share. This is strikingly different from the well-known result derived in fully covered markets, which states that the size of the economy’s production of quality is equal under duopoly and socially optimal outcomes (see Crampes and Hollander 1995). Our new finding may have important policy implications for achieving efficient levels of quality in markets.

Our Proposition 3 complements existing literature in an interesting way. In monopolistic markets, Mussa and Rosen (1978) and Cooper (1984) show that there will be quality distortions for all qualities below the highest quality. Thus, the monopoly sells a lower than socially optimal quality to all consumers having lower tastes than the maximum. In a variant of the standard model, Srinagesh and Bradburd (1989) demonstrate that there will be no quality distortion at the bottom quality level, and there will be enhancement of all qualities for higher consumer tastes. By using a version of the Mussa and Rosen (1978) model with the duopoly competition, we have demonstrated that both bottom and top qualities become distorted under duopolistic price competition.9

Finally, it is interesting to compare the features of socially optimal quality provision under fixed and variable costs. The major difference between these two cases is as follows. Under fixed costs only one quality variant of the good is provided. Both variants are optimal under variable costs, and in addition provision of the high quality

9 We would like to thank the referee for pointing out how Proposition 3 is related to literature in monopolistic competition.

(22)

variant is greater than in the case of fixed production costs. In a duopoly equilibrium, we also showed that the quality spread is too wide under variable costs. Under fixed costs, a duopoly produces two variants, but quality is too low relative to the social optimum (characterized by just one variant).

4. Conclusion

We have considered vertical product differentiation under the assumption of partial market coverage to characterize the social welfare and profit maximizing duopoly outcomes in terms of quality provision and quantities produced. We analyzed this issue both under fixed and variable convex costs of production. Under the assumption of fixed costs, the high quality firm has higher profits and greater market share than the low quality firm. Unlike in the duopoly equilibrium, however, we demonstrated that it is socially optimal to provide only the single (high) quality commodity and to set low quality production to zero. As production is costless, the social planner should charge a uniform price that just covers the costs of quality provision. This socially optimal pricing entails serving half of the market, which interestingly is less than the duopoly serves.

planner should charge a uniform price that just covers the costs of quality provision.

Finally, comparing social welfare maximizing and duopoly outcomes, we find that the spread of product differentiation is too wide under variable costs. Under fixed costs, two variants will be produced in the duopoly, but quality will be too low.

(23)

References

Acharyya, R. 1998. Monopoly and Product Quality: Separating of Pooling Menu?

Economics Letters,61, 187-194.

Cooper, R. 1984. On allocative distortions in problems of self-selection. Rand Journal of Economics 15, 568-577.

Crampes C. and A. Hollander 1995. Duopoly and Quality Standards.European Economic Review 39, 71-82.

Cremer, H. and J. Thisse. 1999. On the Taxation of Polluting Products in a Differentiated Industry.European Economic Review, 43, 575-594,95-106.

Ecchia, G., L. Lambertini and C. Scarpa 2002. On the Regulation of Vertically Differentiated Markets through Minimum Quality Standards. Rivista di Politica Economica 912, 163-202.

Kuhn, M. 2000. Low Quality Leadership in Vertically Differentiated Duopoly. University of York, Department of Economics, Working Paper Series.

Lambertini, L. 1996. Choosing Roles in a Duopoly for Endogenously Differentiated Products.Australian Economics Papers, 205-223.

Lehmann-Grube, U. 1997. Strategic Choice of Quality When Quality is Costly: the Persistence of the High-Quality Advantage, Rand Journal of Economics, 28, 372- 384.

Motta, M. 1993. Endogenous Quality Choice: Price vs. Quantity Competition. Journal of Industrial Economics, 41:113-32.

Mussa M. and S. Rosen 1978. Monopoly and Product Quality. Journal of Economic Theory18, 301-317.

Ronnen, U. 1991. Minimum Quality Standards, Fixed Costs and Competition. Rand Journal of Economics, 22, 490-504.

Shaked, A. and J. Sutton. 1982. Relaxing Price Competition Through Product Differentiation,Review of Economic Studies,XLIX, 3-13.

Shaked, A. and J. Sutton. 1983. Natural Oligopolies,Econometrica,51:5, 1469-1483.

Srinagesh, P. and R. Bradburd 1989. Quality Distortion by a Discriminating Monopolist.

American Economic Review 79, 96-105.

Tirole, J. 1988.The Theory of Industrial Organization. MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass.

Wauthy, Z. 1996. Quality Choice in Models of Vertical Differentiation, Journal of Industrial Economics,XLIV, 345-353.

(24)

Appendix: Social welfare and pricing under fixed costs

Given the socially optimal quality sw b

2 θ 2

= and the cost of providing this quality

s b c w

) 8 (

θ4

= , the social welfare function is defined by,



 

∫ −

=

∫ −

= θ

θ θ

θ

θ θ θ θ

θ θ

c w

c

w d

s b c d s

SW ( ) 2 4

2 2

, (A.1)

where θc is the critical value of taste parameter. Recall that

2

θc =θ when the price is set to cover costs of quality provision. Using this, social welfare becomes,

16 0

4 >

= b SW c

θ

θ . (A.2) Suppose now that the price is set at a higher level, p′> pW. Under a higher price the indifference relation, θ′swp′=0, implies θ′>θc. Suppose that θ′−θc =ζ >0. Under this higher price, the social welfare function is given by,





 −

=

=

∫ ∫

+ +

θ ζ θ θ

ζ θ

θ θ θ θ

θ θ

c c

b d s

c d s

SW w w

4 ) 2

(

2 2

. (A.3)

Solving the resulting social welfare yields,

SW c b

16

) 4 4

( 2 2

2 θ ζ ζθ

θ

ζ θ

= −

+ (A.4)

Taking the difference

4 0 ) ( 16

) 4 4 ( 16

2 2

2 2

4 − − − = + >

=

+

b b

SW b

SW c c

θ ζ θ ζ θ ζ ζ θ θ θ

ζ θ

θ (A.5)

The result that (A.5) is positive demonstrates that pricing by p′> pWis suboptimal. This provides the basis for Proposition 2.

Viittaukset

LIITTYVÄT TIEDOSTOT

Kela developed the new service in partnership with  the  Ministry of Social Affairs and Health (STM), the National  Institute  for  Health  and  Welfare  of 

When there are externalities from quality and the minimum quality stan- dard takes the form of a unit emission standard, an exogenous unit emission standard set just below the level

Briefly, we could summarize that informal employment is characterized by the lack of a contract and social security coverage and that precarious employment is characterized by a

In marine monitoring Earth Observation profoundly increases the temporal resolution and spatial coverage of data on water quality parameters, giving a more comprehensive picture

We show that there exists a separating signaling equilibrium that satisfies the Intuitive Criterion and we compare welfare between the competitive market and the screening and

The aim was to test which theoretical prediction dominated in the market – price regulation and the possibility to cut costs through quality or quality competition, which by the

The purpose of this study was to document and statistically analyse changes in fertiliser use, important quality factors and the connection between fertiliser use and grain quality

expenditures of the welfare state (i.e. education, health care, employment, housing and social serv- ices). In the future the greatest pressure to continuing growth of