• Ei tuloksia

Iterative Game Approach for Modeling the Behavior of Agents in a Competitive Flexibility Trading

N/A
N/A
Info
Lataa
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Jaa "Iterative Game Approach for Modeling the Behavior of Agents in a Competitive Flexibility Trading"

Copied!
12
0
0

Kokoteksti

(1)

Iterative Game Approach for Modeling the Behavior of Agents in a Competitive

Flexibility Trading

MAHOOR EBRAHIMI 1, AMIN SHOKRI GAZAFROUDI2, MAHAN EBRAHIMI3, HANNU LAAKSONEN 1, (Member, IEEE),

MIADREZA SHAFIE-KHAH 1, (Senior Member, IEEE), AND JOÃO P. S. CATALÃO 4, (Senior Member, IEEE)

1School of Technology and Innovations, University of Vaasa, 65200 Vaasa, Finland

2Institute for Automation and Applied Informatics, Karlsruhe Institute of Technology (KIT), 76131 Karlsruhe, Germany 3Department of Electrical Engineering, Sharif University of Technology, Tehran 1458889694, Iran

4Faculty of Engineering, University of Porto, Porto 4200-465, Portugal

Corresponding authors: Amin Shokri Gazafroudi (shokri@kit.edu) and Miadreza Shafie-Khah (mshafiek@uwasa.fi)

The work of Amin Shokri Gazafroudi was supported by the CoNDyNet2 Project funded by the German Federal Ministry of Education and Research under Grant 03EK3055E.

ABSTRACT The potential of end-users to modify their consumption pattern makes them an interesting resource for providing energy flexibility in energy communities. Thus, active end-users require sufficient incentives and automated trading and management schemes. In order to enable increased small-scale end- users participation for flexibility service provision, a new design for flexibility trading is required to model the behavior of different agents and their interactions in energy communities. The novelty of our work lies in proposing an iterative game-based approach in which all agents – consisting of the distribution system operator (DSO), aggregators, and customers– can determine their decision variables to optimize their own objective functions and interact with others to modify their decisions according to others’ decisions.

In addition, three scenarios are considered to study the effects of agents’ freedom while setting their decision variables (by removing one of their constraints in their corresponding decision-making problem). Moreover, the impact of the presence of interruptible loads in comparison with shiftable loads is investigated in this paper. According to the simulation results, it is found that in the scenario where end-users have fewer constraints, in presence of interruptible loads, end-users gain greater income compared to the absence of interruptible loads.

INDEX TERMS Aggregators, energy community, flexibility management, game-based approach, local energy trading.

I. INTRODUCTION A. BACKGROUND

Due to the increase in the utilization of renewable energies as variable and non-dispatchable resources, the power system is facing new problems related to the balance between demand and generation [1]. In this regard, new resources for providing the required balance management and other flexibility ser- vices are needed [2]. End-users can provide energy flexibility for the power system due to their ability to modify their con- sumption [3]. For instance, by adjusting their loads, utilizing

The associate editor coordinating the review of this manuscript and approving it for publication was Abdullah Iliyasu .

the energy storage systems, or making use of the thermal inertia of buildings, end-users can provide flexibility for the system [4]. As a consequence, they are more engaged in the decisions related to the local community [5]. Therefore, con- ventional centralized approaches are not efficient enough to model the active participation of end-users [6]. In this regard, new approaches are needed to model the new type of energy transactions and interactions among different agents in the local communities. Several works proposed new models to follow the active behavior of end-users in energy and flexibil- ity markets. In [7], a theoretical and mathematical foundation for the decentralized participation of consumers in the energy market has been presented. Moreover, challenges related to

(2)

the specific characteristics of decentralized participation of flexible demands have been addressed in [7]. Furthermore, authors in [8] proposed an energy management mechanism to pave the way for residential buildings with distributed resources to trade energy in the distribution system. Ref. [9]

proposed a decentralized mechanism to manage the operation of electric vehicles in charging mode and energy flexibility provided by end-users.

Some papers in the literature concentrated on the novel frameworks for flexibility trading in the distribution system.

In [10], the authors proposed a two-stage approach that enables end-users to trade flexibility and energy in a peer- to-peer (P2P) platform that is supervised by the local mar- ket operator and the DSO. The authors in [11], presented a chance-constrained approach to manage uncertainties in the flexibility transaction among microgrids and the DSO.

In [12], a pricing and bidding mechanism is proposed for the local flexibility market to boost its coupling with other markets such as retail, ancillary service, and the wholesale market. Ref. [13] proposed a stochastic model for optimal bidding strategy of aggregated prosumers to facilitate their flexibility provision. In this way, the uncertainty related to the PV generation, loads, outdoor temperature, and end-users’

behavior has been considered by deploying scenario-based programming. In [14], a distributed local flexibility market is proposed where the uncertainty of demand and network con- gestion have been considered to assist the DSO in reserving and utilizing the demand flexibility most efficiently.

It is crystal clear that Handling the power system consist- ing of a large number of prosumers who are in charge of providing the system flexibility is very difficult. Therefore, an agent e.g aggregator is needed to aggregate energy and flexibility provided by prosumers. Authors in [15] presented a model for local flexibility market where aggregators con- trol different devices for providing various services in the distribution system. In [16], the authors presented a decen- tralized market design in which aggregators are in charge of motivating prosumers to provide energy flexibility for the DSO. Authors in [17] proposed a two-stage stochastic optimization to facilitate the engagement of aggregators in energy and ancillary service markets. In ref. [18], the per- formance of aggregators for delivering the provided flexi- bility by residential end-users to the DSO in presence of large uncertainties is evaluated. In [19], authors proposed a control strategy based on a decentralized bottom-up approach to utilize the flexibility potentials of virtual power plants.

Authors in [20] presented a cooperative market mechanism to determine energy transaction and price for micro-grids in isolated and connected modes considering the uncertainty of renewable energy sources and demand.

In addition to the necessity of the presence of an agent to aggregate the provided flexibility on the demand side, it should be noted that prosumers have a right to trade flexibility with the DSO directly owing to their important role in providing flexibility [21]. In this way, flexibility trading in the distribution system will be more competitive. Thus,

an approach is needed to model the competition between different agents and their interactions. In this respect, a part of the literature deployed the models based on the game theory. Game-based approaches allow modeling the behavior of strategic agents and interactions among them by presenting a mathematical framework [22]. This characteristic makes the game-based approach an ideal method for modeling the energy and flexibility trading in energy communities. The proposed approach in [22] is based on a game theory analysis to investigate the behavior of the flexibility providers and their optimal strategy for choosing the best business partner that maximizes their profit. In [23], the demand response management problem has been studied using a game among utility companies and end-users. The proposed approach in [23] deployed the Stackelberg game between utility com- panies and end-users. The goal of utility companies and end-users is to optimize their income and payment, respec- tively. In [24], monopolistic and game-based approaches for trading energy flexibility are presented and compared. In this regard, in the monopolistic method, just aggregators or con- sumers decide on flexibility management. In addition, two scenarios are considered for the game-based approach, where in the first scenario, the DSO and aggregators are strategic agents and in the second scenario, the DSO and aggregators are the decision-maker agents.

Additionally, in [25], authors proposed a generic model for the geographical and economic evaluation of the flexi- bility potentials of the alternative flexibility providers using cooperative game theory. In [26], a two-level game is used for demand response management. In this regard, in the bottom level, households determine their purchased demand from utility companies according to the power price, and utility companies define their generation and price accord- ing to the power demand of residential users at the higher level. Ref. [27] presented a decentralized approach scheme for energy transactions among microgrids based on a game.

In [28], an event-driven approach is proposed for energy trading between microgrids. For this sake, in their game- based model, authors deployed the concept of reward to make an incentive for the transaction. In [29], a design based on contributions is used for energy trading among microgrids in a competitive market. In this regard, energy is collected from providers and distributed to the consumers according to their historical contributions. Ref. [30] pro- posed a game-theoretic model in which aggregators com- pete with each other to maximize their profit by selling the demand response to the distribution system company.

In [31], a novel scheme has been proposed for a non-convex community energy management problem based on the game theory and the constraints of resources. Ref. [32] presented a stochastic multi-layer model to investigate the behavior of different players in the electricity market. In their proposed approach, consumers are in charge of selecting their supply- ing agent using a game-theoretic model. Therefore, supplying agents should compete with each other to maintain their customers.

(3)

B. CONTRIBUTION

In the literature, numerous studies have been performed to propose an ideal framework for transacting energy flexibility in energy communities. Among all proposed solutions, game- based approaches are more applicable and realistic because they model the behavior of agents to empower them to make a decision independently. An important point in this approach is that the interaction among all agents should be consid- ered while making decisions. However, complete interaction among the DSO, aggregators and end-users has not been modeled in the literature. To the best of the authors’ knowl- edge, a framework in which all agents including end-users, aggregators, and the DSO can decide independently and mod- ify their decisions has been proposed in none of the papers in the literature. In this paper, we propose an iterative game for modeling the rational behavior of all agents (end-users, aggregators, and the DSO) in a competitive flexibility trading in which agents can play their role and change their decisions according to the other agents’ decisions. The contribution of this paper can be summarized as follows:

A novel iterative game-based algorithm is proposed for modeling the flexibility transaction in the energy com- munity considering interactions among all agents.

Effects of shiftable and interruptible loads based on the portion of interruptible loads are studied.

Three flexibility scenarios are considered (by removing one of their constraints in their corresponding decision- making problem) for assessing the impact of the freedom of agents on their decisions and validating the simulation results.

Our proposed iterative game-based approach has some advantages compared to other methods used in the literature.

Firstly, it provides a competitive trading framework where all players have their decision variables and can solve their prob- lems independently to find their optimal solutions. All agents in our proposed approach are engaged in the decision-making process, while there are limited decision-maker agents in other approaches. Secondly, our approach provides an equal power for all agents to update their decisions based on the last decisions of others, because the trading problem is solved from all agents’ points of view considering their optimal strategies. For instance, bilevel optimization methodology solves the optimization problem from the leader’s point of view. The autonomy of the followers in the bilevel optimiza- tion model is way less than the leader of the problem, as the leader can consider the objective function and constraints of the followers as a constraint in its optimization problem, to anticipate the logical actions of followers, while followers do not have a similar ability. In this regard, our proposed approach considers a similar power for all agents to make and update their decisions and prevents monopoly in the transaction process to serve the players with a competitive trading platform.

Furthermore, since our approach empowers all agents for making their decisions independently and modifying them based on others’ decisions, it can simulate the real behavior

of agents for flexibility trading where all agents have their optimal strategies. In this way, the energy sector policy-maker can study the trading behaviors and interactions of agents.

This will enable the policy-maker to investigate the impacts of new regulations and rules on the agents’ behavior and trading platform.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In SectionII, the problem formulation is presented. Section III explains three scenarios for studying the impact of agents’ decision- making freedom. Section IV describes our iterative game-based algorithm which is deployed for energy flex- ibility management. Simulation results for the 33-bus test system are discussed in SectionV. Finally, our conclusions are presented in VI.

II. PROPOSED MODEL A. PROBLEM FORMULATION

In this section, we explain our proposed model for transacting energy flexibility between agents in the energy community, i.e. end-users, aggregators, and the DSO, as illustrated in Fig.1. In our model, end-users, aggregators, and the DSO transact flexibility in a hierarchical structure. In this way, the total energy transacted among end-users and aggrega- tors is traded through aggregators and the DSO. In addition, end-users can trade flexibility with both their corresponding aggregator and the DSO. In this way, the monopoly is pre- vented, and the freedom of agents for participation in flex- ibility trading is promoted. Moreover, when end-users have the opportunity to trade flexibility with both the aggregators and the DSO, they are motivated to be more involved in the flexibility provision [21]. These factors can pave the path toward a competitive trading framework. It is considered that each aggregator has a bilateral contract with its corre- sponding end-users. In this way, end-users and aggregators can transact flexibility in both directions. Each end-user can adjust its load to provide positive or negative energy flexi- bility as represented in Eq. (1). Here,Ljtf is the amount of flexibility provided by end-user j at time slott, and Ljtc is the scheduled load of end-userj. Besides,Ljt represents the

FIGURE 1. Interaction among agents in our proposed local flexibility trading model.

(4)

load of end-userjafter providing the flexibility in real-time.

Accordingly, Eq. (2) presents the upper and lower bounds for provision flexibility of end-users. Here,γjrepresents the flexibility factor which is introduced in [24]. The flexibility provided by an end-user is traded with the DSO or aggregator or both of them. The relation between the energy flexibility provided by an end-user (Ljtf) and its flexibility traded with the DSO (PD2Ljt ) and its corresponding aggregator (PL2Ajt ) is represented in (3).

Ljt =LjtcLjtf,∀j,t (1)

−γjLjtcLjtf ≤γjLjtc,∀j,t (2) Ljtf =PL2AjtPD2Ljt ,∀j,t (3) Furthermore, Loads of end-users have been categorized into three general classifications; non-flexible, shiftable, and interruptible loads. Thus, shiftable and interruptible loads have the potential to be a source of flexibility, while end-users cannot adjust non-flexible loads for the sake of flexibility provision. The portion of interruptible and shiftable loads of consumers is described in (4) and Fig. 2. In this way, the portion of interruptible loads is determined by settingα. Ifα=0, energy consumption after providing flexibility over a time horizon, e.g. 24 hours, should be equal to the energy of scheduled load in the assumed time horizon. In other words, the sum of provided flexibility over a time horizon must be equal to zero by setting α = 0. In this case, all flexible loads are shiftable. As the amount of α increases, the difference between the sum of scheduled load and the sum of the real-time load over a time horizon can be bigger which increases the portion of the interruptible load of end- userj. In addition, as mentioned before, end-users can trade flexibility with aggregators. In this way, if end-user jsells energy flexibility to its corresponding aggregator, PL2Ajt is positive. However, if end-userjbuys energy flexibility from its corresponding aggregator,PL2Ajt is negative. Moreover, the relation between flexibility traded among aggregatorkand its end-users (PL2Ajt ), and flexibility traded among aggregatork and the DSO (PA2Dkt ) is presented in (5).

−αγj

X

t

Ljtc ≤X

t

Ljtf ≤αγj

X

t

Ljtc,∀j (4)

PA2Dkt = X

j∈Ak

PL2Ajt ,∀k,t (5)

FIGURE 2. Definition of interruptible and shiftable portions for flexible loads.

In our proposed structure, the DSO and end-users are also able to trade flexibility in both directions. The positive sign of PD2Ljt is considered for the trade of flexibility from the DSO to the end-userj, whereas if the DSO buys flexibility from end-user j, PD2Ljt is negative. Additionally, end-users determine the amount of flexibility traded with their corre- sponding aggregators,PLjt2A, and the price of flexibility which is exchanged with the DSO,λD2Ljt . To prevent the possibility of arbitrage in the flexibility transaction between end-users and aggregators, upper and lower limits are considered for PL2Ajt which is represented in (6). In addition, maximum and minimum limits related toλD2Ljt which is the decision variable of end-users is presented in (7).

−γjLjtcPL2Ajt ≤γjLjtc,∀j,t (6)

−λL2Akt ≤λD2Ljt ≤λL2Akt ,∀j,t (7) On the other hand, aggregators determine the price of their flexibility transacted with the DSO, λA2Djt . The upper and lower bands ofλA2Djt are presented in (8).

δktλL2Akt ≤λA2Dkt ≤λrtt ,∀t,k (8) Finally, the DSO sets the flexibility traded among the DSO and end-users,PD2Ljt . A limitation is considered for PD2Ljt , in both directions, to prevent the possibility of arbitrage in flexibility trading among end-users and the DSO as presented in Eq. (9). Moreover, the DSO transacts flexibility with the RTEM and all agents as expressed in (10).

−γjLjtcPD2Ljt ≤γjLjtc,∀j,t (9) Prtt =X

j

PD2Ljt −X

k

PA2Dkt ,∀t (10)

B. AGENTS’ OBJECTIVE FUNCTIONS

In this section, we introduce objective functions of end- users, aggregators and the DSO which are presented in (11), (12) and (13), respectively. As seen in (11), the objective function of end-userjconsists of two parts. The first term represents the cost of buying flexibility from the DSO and the second term expresses the income of selling flexibility to its corresponding aggregator. The objective function of aggregators also consists of two parts consisting of the cost of exchanging flexibility with end-users and the income of flexibility exchanging with the DSO, accordingly. However, the DSO is in charge of minimizing the trade with the RTEM to increase the self-sufficiency of the distribution system.

Fig.1shows interactions among agents and decision-making flow in our proposed energy flexibility trading model.

OFjeu=X

j

X

t

λD2Ljt PD2Ljt

−X

t

X

j

λL2Akt PL2Ajt ,jAk (11)

OFkag =X

t

X

j

λL2Akt PL2Ajt

(5)

FIGURE 3. Problems of agents and their constraints in scenario 1.

−X

t

λA2Dkt PA2Dkt ,∀jAk (12)

OFdso =X

t

λrtt |Prtt | (13)

III. SCENARIOS DEFINITION

In this paper, three different scenarios are defined in which the DSO and end-users have different levels of freedom for determining their decision variables due to the pres- ence or absence of the constraint on the amount of the traded flexibility between end-users and the DSO (Eq. (9)), as well as the constraint on the amount of the traded flexi- bility between end-users and their corresponding aggregator (Eq. (6)). On the other hand, the freedom of aggregators is constant in all scenarios. In this regard, the freedom of end-users and the DSO is increased by removing one of their constraints in their corresponding decision-making problem.

As mentioned in SectionII, (6) and (9) were the constraints related to preventing the possibility of arbitrage. Therefore, with their absence and presence, there are different levels of arbitrage avoidance. we consider three scenarios to analyze the behavior of the agents in the presence or absence of the arbitrage prevention constraints. Our proposed scenarios are explained in the following:

Scenario 1: In scenario 1, the constraints of end-users’

problem is composed of (2), (3), (4), (6), and (7). Aggre- gators problem consists of 2 constraints; (5) and (8).

In addition, (2), (3), (4), and (9) are the constraints of the DSO’s problem in this scenario. Presence of ((6)) in the problem of end-users, indicates that a restriction is set to prevent the possibility of arbitrage in the flexibility transaction between end-users and their corresponding aggregators. Furthermore, a limitation is imposed by (9) in the problem of the DSO to prevent the possibility of arbitrage in the flexibility transaction among end-users and the DSO. The objective function and constraints of all agents in scenario 1 is shown in Fig. 3

Scenario 2: In scenario 2, problems of aggregators and the DSO are the same as scenario 1. However, in this sce- nario, (6) is removed from the constraints of end-users’

problem. Therefore, an arbitrage may occur in the flex- ibility transaction between end-users and aggregators.

FIGURE 4. Problems of agents and their constraints in scenario 2.

FIGURE 5. Problems of agents and their constraints in scenario 3.

However, owing to the presence of (9) in the constraints of the DSO’s problem, the possibility of arbitrage in the flexibility transaction among the DSO and end-users is prevented. The objective function and constraints of all agents in scenario 2 is shown in Fig. 4.

Scenario 3: In scenario 3, the problems of end-users and aggregators are similar to scenario 1. However, in this scenario, (9) is removed from the constraints of the DSO’s problem. Therefore, an arbitrage may occur in the flexibility trading between end-users and the DSO.

However, owing to the presence of (6) in the constraints of the end-users’ problem, the possibility of arbitrage in the flexibility transaction among aggregators and end-users is prevented. Agents’ objective functions and constraints in scenario 3 are presented in Fig. 5.

IV. PROPOSED FLEXIBILITY TRADING

In this paper, we proposed an iterative game-based approach that enables players to make and update their decisions, as shown in Fig. 6. Since the decision variables of one agent may be a parameter in the objective function of other agents, the decision of each agent influences the optimal decision of other agents. In this regard, all agents are able to make their optimal decisions by optimizing their objective functions and finding the optimal value for their assigned decision variables. Then, in the next iteration, they can update their decision variables based on the last decisions of other agents. In this way, firstly, end-users solve their problem

(6)

FIGURE 6. Flowchart of the proposed iterative game-based algorithm.

(problemE), and set their decision variables,PL2Ajt andλD2Ljt , according to the initialized inputs and parameters. In the next step, aggregators find an optimal solution for their problem (problemA), and determine the amount ofλA2Dkt . Moreover, PA2Dkt is calculated according toPL2Ajt determined in the pre- vious step by end-users. Finally, the DSO solves its problem (ProblemD) and determines the amount ofPD2Ljt . It is clear that the decision of the DSO depends on the previous deci- sions of end-users and aggregators in each iteration. Hence, the amount of PL2Ajt affects the optimal amount of PD2Ljt for ProblemD. AfterPD2Ljt is obtained, the decision-making procedure will be ended if the convergence condition is met as presented by (14). On the other hand, if Eq. (14) has not been met, the proposed game procedure will be iterated. This way, end-users make their decisions according to the updated value ofPD2Ljt which is determined by the DSO. Then,PD2Ljt affects both decisions of end-users. Furthermore, it impacts on the constraints ofPL2Ajt according to (2) and (3). Moreover, the direction of the flexibility traded between the DSO and end-users influences the optimal value ofλD2Ljt .

In this paper, we proposed an iterative game-based approach where the decision of each agent influences the decision of other agents as shown in Fig. 6. Thus, all agents are able to make their optimal decisions and update their decision variables in an iterative interaction with other agents.

In this way, firstly, end-users solve their problem (problem E), and set their decision variables,PL2Ajt andλD2Ljt , according to the initialized inputs and parameters. In the next step, aggregators find an optimal solution for their problem (prob- lemA), and determine the amount ofλA2Dkt . Moreover,PA2Dkt is calculated according to PL2Ajt determined in the previous step by end-users. Finally, the DSO solves its problem (Prob- lem D) and determines the amount ofPD2Ljt . It is clear that the decision of the DSO depends on the previous decisions of end-users and aggregators in each iteration. Hence, the amount of PL2Ajt affects the optimal amount of PD2Ljt for Problem D. After PD2Ljt is obtained, the decision-making procedure will be ended if the convergence condition is met as presented by (14). On the other hand, if Eq. (14) has not been met, the proposed game procedure will be iterated.

This way, end-users update their decision variables based on the last value ofPD2Ljt which was determined by the DSO.

FIGURE 7. 33-bus test system [21], [24].

As, PD2Ljt affects both decisions of end-users, and impacts on the constraints ofPL2Ajt according to (2) and (3). More- over, the direction of the flexibility traded between the DSO and end-users influences the optimal value ofλD2Ljt . After end-users update their decisions, the aggregators and the DSO update their decision variables based on the last decision of end-user. This procedure is repeated and agents update their decisions until the convergence condition is met. In general, iterative approaches do not have deterministic convergence criteria. We considered a convergence criterion that is repre- sented in Eq.14. The convergence criterion of our approach is based on the difference between agents’ objective functions in two consecutive iterations. In this way, the summation of variations of the agents’ objective functions in two consecu- tive iterations must be less than a sufficiently small value.

(|OFEU(i)−OFEU(i−1)| +|OFA(i)−OFA(i−1)|

+|OFdso(i)−OFdso(i−1)|)/(|OFEU(i)|

+|OFA(i)| + |OFdso(i)|)< (14) V. SIMULATION RESULTS

A. CASE STUDY

In this paper, a 33-bus test system is used from [21], [24] to assess our proposed flexibility trading algorithm between agents in the energy community as shown in Fig. 7.

Three regions have been considered which are managed by their corresponding aggregators. The price data of energy traded between end-users and aggregators is came from [21].

Besides, we assume thatγj=0.1, andδkt =1.1 according to Refs. [21], [24], respectively. In addition, it is considered that loads are totally shiftable (α = 0). Our proposed flexibility management problem is solved in MATLAB using particle swarm optimization (PSO) for determining the optimal deci- sion of each agent in each iteration. Thus, agents solve their problem in each iteration independently via PSO.

B. SCENARIOS DISCUSSION 1) SCENARIO 1

In this scenario in which none of the constraints of end-users and the DSO is removed, and both the DSO and end-users are

(7)

FIGURE 8. Objective function of end-users, aggregators, and the DSO in different iterations (Scenario 1).

TABLE 1. Objective function for end-users, aggregators and the DSO in different scenarios [e].

more restricted for making their decisions, after 59 iterations the convergence condition is met. Fig. 8 shows the amount of objective function of end-users, aggregators, and the DSO in different iterations. As shown in this figure, aggregators are able to achieve a negative value for their objective function which means that flexibility trading is profitable for them.

On the other hand, while end-users in the first iteration can gain income due to the negative value of their objective function, decisions of other agents push them to have a positive objective function in other iterations. It can also be realized that like aggregators, fluctuation of end-users’

objective function in different iterations is very low. However, the fluctuation of DSO’s objective function is considerable.

It shows that decisions of end-users have a significant effect on the maximum and minimum band ofPD2Ljt , according to Eq.9,2, and3. Therefore, the objective function of the DSO fluctuates with different decisions of end-users.

Figs. 10 and 9 shows the flexibility traded between aggre- gators and the DSO and their price accordingly. It is obvious that when an aggregator buys energy flexibility from the DSO (PA2Dkt < 0), it sets the minimum band forλA2Dkt based on Eq. (8) which isδktλL2Akt . On the other hand, when aggregators ksells energy flexibility to the DSO (PA2Dkt >0),λA2Dkt is set on its maximum band (λrtt ). Fig. 11 shows energy flexibility traded among the DSO and the RTEM. It is observed that, in most hours, the amount ofPrtt is near zero. Consequently, the amount of the objective function of the DSO is not considerable according to (13). Table1presents the amount of the objective function of end-users, aggregators, and the DSO in all three scenarios. The objective function of end- users, aggregators, and the DSO in scenario 1 are 943.62e,

−1110.42eand 41.65e, accordingly.

2) SCENARIO 2

In the second scenario where one of the constraints of end-users is removed and they can decide more freely, the convergence condition is met after 11 iterations. The amount

FIGURE 9. Price of flexibility transacted between aggregators and the DSO (Scenario 1).

FIGURE 10. Flexibility traded between aggregators and the DSO (Scenario 1).

FIGURE 11. Real-time energy exchanged between the DSO and the RTEM (Scenario 1).

of objective function of end-users, aggregators, and the DSO in different iterations is shown in fig. 12. Our results show that, in scenario 2, aggregators are more successful in gaining income in comparison with scenario 1, since they can reduce their objective function from −1110.42 in scenario 1 to

−2294.28 in scenario 2. Figs. 14 and 13 show the flexibility traded between aggregators and the DSO and their price in scenario 2 accordingly. It can be understood that the amount of flexibility traded between aggregators and the DSO is more than its amount in scenario 1. So, aggregators are able to increase their income. In all iterations, end-users’ objective function is positive except the first iteration, and finally, in the last iteration, their objective function is 522.46e. Therefore, it is less in comparison with scenario 1 (943.62e), in which they are more restricted while determining decision variables.

Moreover, The objective function of the DSO in the second scenario (3253.48e) is much more than its value in scenario 1 (41.65e). Hence, the objective function of the DSO is about 77 times bigger than scenario 1. Therefore, it can be con- cluded that the freedom of end-users in scenario 2 is very

(8)

FIGURE 12. Objective function for end-users, aggregators, and the DSO in different iterations (Scenario 2).

FIGURE 13. Price of flexibility transacted between aggregators and the DSO (Scenario 2).

FIGURE 14. Flexibility traded between aggregators and the DSO (Scenario 2).

FIGURE 15. Real-time energy exchanged between the DSO and the RTEM (Scenario 2).

destructive for the DSO in such a way that the loss of the DSO is way more than the benefit of end-users and aggregators.

Fig. 15 shows the energy flexibility traded among the DSO and the RTEM. It is seen that its amount is much more than its amount in scenario 1, which causes the objective function of the DSO to increase dramatically according to (13).

FIGURE 16. Objective function for end-users, aggregators, and the DSO in different iterations (Scenario 3).

FIGURE 17. Price of flexibility transacted among aggregators and the DSO (Scenario 3).

3) SCENARIO 3

In this scenario in which one of the constraints of the DSO is removed and it can decide more freely in comparison with scenarios 1 and 2, after 13 iterations the problem is solved. fig. 16, shows the amount of objective functions for end-users, aggregators, and the DSO in different iterations.

In Scenario 3, the DSO is able to improve its performance by decreasing its objective function from 41,65 in scenario 1 to 16,21 in scenario 3 (about 60%). Fig. 15 shows that in most hours the energy flexibility traded among the DSO and the RTEM in scenario 3 is less than its amount in scenario 1.

On the other hand, the objective function of end-users in sce- nario 3 (1228.74e) is more than scenario 1 (943.62e) and scenario 2 (525.46e). Therefore, end-users’ performance in scenario 3 is worse compared to Scenarios 1 and 2. Moreover, aggregators’ objective function in scenario 3 (−1145.49e) is about identical to its objective function in the first scenario (−1110.42 e). Figs. 18 and 17 show the flexibility traded between aggregators and the DSO and their price in scenario 3 accordingly. It is noticeable that the adverse effect of end- users’ freedom on the DSO’s objective function is much more than the adverse impact of DSO’s freedom on end-users’

objective function. Because the objective function of the DSO in scenario 2 (3253.48e) is about 7700 percent more than its objective function in scenario 1 (41.65e). However, the objective function of end-users in scenario 3 (1228.74 e) is just 30% more than their objective function in scenario 1 (943.62e).

(9)

FIGURE 18. Flexibility traded between aggregators and the DSO (Scenario 3).

FIGURE 19. Real-time energy exchanged between the DSO and the RTEM (Scenario 3).

TABLE 2. Objective functions for end-users, aggregators and the DSO in different scenarios for interruptible loads (α=0.1) [e].

C. PRESENCE OF INTERRUPTIBLE LOADS

In the previous sections, it has been assumed that loads of end-users only consist of shiftable loads (α = 0). In this section, the behavior of different agents in presence of inter- ruptible loads is assessed. Tables2 and3 show the amount of objective functions of agents for α = 0.1 and α = 0.15 accordingly. Fig. 20, using a radar plot, depicts the objective function of end-users and aggregators in differ- ent scenarios in presence of shiftable loads (α = 0) and interruptible loads (α = 0.1 and α = 0.15). As seen in scenario 2, the amount of objective function of end-users decreases asα increases. On the other hand, in scenario 3, the objective function of end-users increases asαincreases.

However, in scenario 1, with increasingαfrom 0 to 0.1 objec- tive function of end-users increases, and with increasing α from 0.1 to 0.15 objective function of end-users decreases.

In addition, aggregators’ objective function in scenarios 1 and 2 decreases asαincreases. This trend is not similar in scenario 3. Because with increasingαfrom 0 to 0.1 objective function of aggregators decreases and with increasingαfrom 0.1 to 0.15 objective function of aggregators increases. Unlike aggregators and end-users, the DSO has a similar trend in all scenarios. The objective function of the DSO increases with increasingα.

TABLE 3.Objective function for end-users, aggregators and the DSO in different scenarios for interruptible loads (α=0.15) [e].

FIGURE 20. Objective functions for end-users and aggregators in different scenarios forα=0,α=0.1, andα=0.15.

D. CHALLENGES

The challenges of our proposed model should be taken into account in our future works to improve the quality of our proposed trading framework. For instance, Peer-to-peer (P2P) flexibility trading possibility that can incentivize peers to be actively involved in flexibility provision for the local energy communities, will be addressed in our future works.

However, there will be serious scalability issues in the P2P trading platform as there are complex interactions among end-users. While in our approach, there is no interaction between end-users. Therefore, increasing the scale of the distribution system has no serious impact on the performance of our proposed approach. In addition, as there is no coupling constraint between end-users’ flexibility trading, the compu- tational burden of our approach is very low. Therefore, our approach does not require high computational units. In addi- tion, the distribution network topology and optimal power flow that is missing in our work can be considered for shaping an energy flexibility market platform.

VI. CONCLUSION

In this paper, we proposed a novel iterative game-based algorithm based on a complete interaction among agents for trading energy flexibility in the energy community. We con- sidered three scenarios assigning different levels of freedom to end-users and the DSO in presence of both shiftable and interruptible loads for evaluating our proposed model.

According to the simulation results, it is found that:

In almost all situations end-users and aggregators have a similar performance in the presence of shiftable loads.

The removal of one of end-users’ constraints has a destructive effect on the performance of the DSO.

(10)

The presence of interruptible loads causes the objective function of end-users to be less when they have fewer constraints.

With increasing the portion of the interruptible loads, the condition of aggregators improves in almost all of the situations.

As the portion of interruptible loads increases the objec- tive function of the DSO increases.

In this work, peer-to-peer energy trading among end-users have not been addressed. In our future work, we will study a flexibility market considering distribution network con- straints where end-users can transact flexibility through peer- to-peer sharing. In addition, we will study the potential of end-user for providing flexibility such as adjusting the loads, utilizing energy storage systems, and making use of the ther- mal inertia of the buildings in more detail by considering a comprehensive model for each of them.

REFERENCES

[1] H. Li, Z. Lu, Y. Qiao, B. Zhang, and Y. Lin, ‘‘The flexibility test system for studies of variable renewable energy resources,’’IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 36, no. 2, pp. 1526–1536, Mar. 2021.

[2] M. S. H. Nizami, M. J. Hossain, and K. Mahmud, ‘‘A nested transac- tive energy market model to trade demand-side flexibility of residen- tial consumers,’’IEEE Trans. Smart Grid, vol. 12, no. 1, pp. 479–490, Jan. 2021.

[3] C. A. Correa-Florez, A. Michiorri, and G. Kariniotakis, ‘‘Optimal participation of residential aggregators in energy and local flexibil- ity markets,’’IEEE Trans. Smart Grid, vol. 11, no. 2, pp. 1644–1656, Mar. 2020.

[4] S. Lu, W. Gu, K. Meng, S. Yao, B. Liu, and Z. Y. Dong, ‘‘Thermal inertial aggregation model for integrated energy systems,’’IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 35, no. 3, pp. 2374–2387, May 2020.

[5] C. Schick, N. Klempp, and K. Hufendiek, ‘‘Role and impact of prosumers in a sector-integrated energy system with high renewable shares,’’ IEEE Trans. Power Syst., early access, Nov. 26, 2020, doi:

10.1109/TPWRS.2020.3040654.

[6] A. S. Gazafroudi, J. M. Corchado, M. Shafie-Khah, M. Lotfi, and P. S. J. Catalao, ‘‘Iterative algorithm for local electricity trading,’’ inProc.

IEEE Milan PowerTech, Jun. 2019, pp. 1–6.

[7] D. Papadaskalopoulos and G. Strbac, ‘‘Decentralized participation of flexible demand in electricity markets—Part I: Market mecha- nism,’’ IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 28, no. 4, pp. 3658–3666, Nov. 2013.

[8] M. S. H. Nizami, M. J. Hossain, and E. Fernandez, ‘‘Multiagent-based transactive energy management systems for residential buildings with distributed energy resources,’’IEEE Trans. Ind. Informat., vol. 16, no. 3, pp. 1836–1847, Mar. 2020.

[9] A. S. Gazafroudi, J. M. Corchado, A. Keane, and A. Soroudi, ‘‘Decen- tralised flexibility management for EVs,’’ IET Renew. Power Gener., vol. 13, no. 6, pp. 952–960, Apr. 2019.

[10] A. S. Gazafroudi, M. Khorasany, R. Razzaghi, H. Laaksonen, and M. Shafie-Khah, ‘‘Hierarchical approach for coordinating energy and flex- ibility trading in local energy markets,’’Appl. Energy, vol. 302, Nov. 2021, Art. no. 117575.

[11] Z. Bagheri, M. Doostizadeh, and F. Aminifar, ‘‘A receding horizon data- driven chance-constrained approach for energy flexibility trading in multi- microgrid distribution network,’’IET Renew. Power Gener., vol. 15, no. 13, pp. 2860–2877, Oct. 2021.

[12] S. Annala, L. Klein, L. Matos, S. Repo, O. Kilkki, A. Narayanan, and S. Honkapuro, ‘‘Framework to facilitate electricity and flexibility trading within, to, and from local markets,’’Energies, vol. 14, no. 11, p. 3229, May 2021.

[13] J. P. Iria, F. J. Soares, and M. A. Matos, ‘‘Trading small prosumers flexibility in the energy and tertiary reserve markets,’’IEEE Trans. Smart Grid, vol. 10, no. 3, pp. 2371–2382, May 2019.

[14] A. Esmat, J. Usaola, and M. Moreno, ‘‘A decentralized local flexibility market considering the uncertainty of demand,’’Energies, vol. 11, no. 8, p. 2078, Aug. 2018.

[15] P. Olivella-Rosell, P. Lloret-Gallego, Ì. Munné-Collado, R. Villafafila-Robles, A. Sumper, S. Ottessen, J. Rajasekharan, and B. Bremdal, ‘‘Local flexibility market design for aggregators providing multiple flexibility services at distribution network level,’’ Energies, vol. 11, no. 4, p. 822, Apr. 2018.

[16] T. Morstyn, A. Teytelboym, and M. D. McCulloch, ‘‘Designing decentral- ized markets for distribution system flexibility,’’IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 34, no. 3, pp. 2128–2139, May 2019.

[17] J. P. Iria, F. J. Soares, and M. A. Matos, ‘‘Trading small prosumers flexibility in the energy and tertiary reserve markets,’’IEEE Trans. Smart Grid, vol. 10, no. 3, pp. 2371–2382, May 2019.

[18] C. Heinrich, C. Ziras, A. L. A. Syrri, and H. W. Bindner, ‘‘EcoGrid 2.0: A large-scale field trial of a local flexibility market,’’Appl. Energy, vol. 261, Mar. 2020, Art. no. 114399.

[19] H. Zhou, S. Fan, Q. Wu, L. Dong, Z. Li, and G. He, ‘‘Stimulus-response control strategy based on autonomous decentralized system theory for exploitation of flexibility by virtual power plant,’’Appl. Energy, vol. 285, Mar. 2021, Art. no. 116424.

[20] R. Bahmani, H. Karimi, and S. Jadid, ‘‘Stochastic electricity market model in networked microgrids considering demand response programs and renewable energy sources,’’Int. J. Electr. Power Energy Syst., vol. 117, May 2020, Art. no. 105606.

[21] C. Zhang, Q. Wang, J. Wang, P. Pinson, J. M. Morales, and J. Østergaard,

‘‘Real-time procurement strategies of a proactive distribution company with aggregator-based demand response,’’IEEE Trans. Smart Grid, vol. 9, no. 2, pp. 766–776, Mar. 2018.

[22] K. Coninx, G. Deconinck, and T. Holvoet, ‘‘Who gets my flex? An evo- lutionary game theory analysis of flexibility market dynamics,’’Appl.

Energy, vol. 218, pp. 104–113, May 2018.

[23] S. Maharjan, Q. Zhu, Y. Zhang, S. Gjessing, and T. Basar, ‘‘Dependable demand response management in the smart grid: A Stackelberg game approach,’’IEEE Trans. Smart Grid, vol. 4, no. 1, pp. 120–132, Mar. 2013.

[24] A. S. Gazafroudi, M. Shafie-Khah, F. Prieto-Castrillo, J. M. Corchado, and J. P. S. Catalão, ‘‘Monopolistic and game-based approaches to transact energy flexibility,’’IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 35, no. 2, pp. 1075–1084, Mar. 2020.

[25] M. Kristiansen, M. Korpås, and H. G. Svendsen, ‘‘A generic framework for power system flexibility analysis using cooperative game theory,’’Appl.

Energy, vol. 212, pp. 223–232, Feb. 2018.

[26] B. Chai, J. Chen, Z. Yang, and Y. Zhang, ‘‘Demand response management with multiple utility companies: A two-level game approach,’’IEEE Trans.

Smart Grid, vol. 5, no. 2, pp. 722–731, Mar. 2014.

[27] J. Lee, J. Guo, J. Choi, and M. Zukerman, ‘‘Distributed energy trad- ing in microgrids: A game-theoretic model and its equilibrium anal- ysis,’’ IEEE Trans. Ind. Electron., vol. 62, no. 6, pp. 3524–3533, Jun. 2015.

[28] S. Park, J. Lee, G. Hwang, and J. K. Choi, ‘‘Event-driven energy trading system in microgrids: Aperiodic market model analysis with a game theoretic approach,’’ IEEE Access, vol. 5, pp. 26291–26302, 2017.

[29] S. Park, J. Lee, S. Bae, G. Hwang, and J. K. Choi, ‘‘Contribution- based energy-trading mechanism in microgrids for future smart grid:

A game theoretic approach,’’IEEE Trans. Ind. Electron., vol. 63, no. 7, pp. 4255–4265, Jul. 2016.

[30] E. Reihani, A. Eshraghi, and M. Motalleb, ‘‘Game theoretic contribution of demand response in real time power provision of distribution sys- tem operator,’’ inProc. North Amer. Power Symp. (NAPS), Sep. 2018, pp. 1–6.

[31] G. Tsaousoglou, P. Pinson, and N. G. Paterakis, ‘‘Transactive energy for flexible prosumers using algorithmic game theory,’’IEEE Trans. Sustain.

Energy, vol. 12, no. 3, pp. 1571–1581, Jul. 2021.

[32] M. Shafie-Khah and J. P. Catalão, ‘‘A stochastic multi-layer agent-based model to study electricity market participants behavior,’’IEEE Trans.

Power Syst., vol. 30, no. 2, pp. 867–881, Mar. 2015.

(11)

MAHOOR EBRAHIMIreceived the B.Sc. degree in electrical engineering and the M.Sc. degree in planning and management of energy sys- tems from the Amirkabir University of Technol- ogy, Tehran, Iran. He is currently pursuing the Ph.D. degree with the University of Vaasa, Vaasa, Finland. His research interests include power mar- ket, flexibility market, optimal operation and plan- ning of multi-carrier energy systems, and demand response.

AMIN SHOKRI GAZAFROUDI received the B.Sc. and M.Sc. degrees in power electrical engi- neering, and the Ph.D. degree in computer science from the University of Salamanca, Salamanca, Spain, in 2019. He is currently a Postdoctoral Researcher with the Energy System Modeling Research Group, Karlsruhe Institute of Technol- ogy (KIT), Karlsruhe, Germany. His research interests include power system and electricity market modeling, power flow and contingency analysis, local energy and flexibility markets design, peer-to-peer energy trading in smart grids, market-based coordination mechanisms, decentralized energy management systems, bidding strategies for autonomous home energy management systems, planning and operation of integrated energy systems, and application of machine learning algorithms on price and demand forecasting.

MAHAN EBRAHIMI received the B.Sc. and M.Sc. degrees in electrical engineering from the Sharif University of Technology, Tehran, Iran, in 2018 and 2021, respectively. He is currently work- ing on energy market simulation with the Sharif University of Technology. His research interests include smart grids, energy markets, power sys- tem optimization, and energy management of vehicle-to-grid.

HANNU LAAKSONEN(Member, IEEE) received the M.Sc. (Tech.) degree in electrical power engi- neering from the Tampere University of Technol- ogy, Tampere, Finland, in 2004, and the Ph.D.

(Tech.) degree in electrical engineering from the University of Vaasa, Vaasa, Finland, in 2011. His employment experience includes working as a Research Scientist at the VTT Technical Research Centre of Finland and at the University of Vaasa.

He worked as a Principal Engineer at ABB Ltd., Vaasa. He is currently a Professor of electrical engineering at the University of Vaasa. He is also the Manager of the Smart Energy Master’s Program.

His research interests include the protection of low-inertia power sys- tems (including microgrids), active management of distributed and flexible energy resources in future smart energy systems as well as future-proof technology and market concepts for smart grids.

MIADREZA SHAFIE-KHAH (Senior Member, IEEE) received the first Ph.D. degree in electri- cal engineering from Tarbiat Modares University, Tehran, Iran, and the second Ph.D. degree in elec- tromechanical engineering from the University of Beira Interior (UBI), Covilha, Portugal. He held a postdoctoral position at the UBI. He held a postdoctoral position at the University of Salerno, Salerno, Italy. He is currently an Associate Pro- fessor at the University of Vaasa, Vaasa, Finland.

He has coauthored more than 440 articles that received more than 8400 cita- tions with an H-index equal to 51. His research interests include power market simulation, market power monitoring, power system optimization, demand response, electric vehicles, price and renewable forecasting, and smart grids. He has won five best paper awards at IEEE conferences. He is an Editor of the IEEE TRANSACTIONS ONSUSTAINABLEENERGY, an Associate Editor of the IEEE SYSTEMSJOURNAL, an Associate Editor of IEEE ACCESS, an Editor of the IEEE OPENACCESSJOURNAL OFPOWER ANDENERGY(OAJPE), an Associate Editor ofIET-RPG, the Guest Editor-in-Chief of the IEEE OPEN ACCESSJOURNAL OFPOWER ANDENERGY(OAJPE), the Guest Editor of the IEEE TRANSACTIONS ONCLOUDCOMPUTING, and the guest editor of more than 14 special issues. He was considered one of the Outstanding Reviewers of the IEEE TRANSACTIONS ONSUSTAINABLEENERGY, in 2014 and 2017, one of the Best Reviewers of the IEEE TRANSACTIONS ONSMARTGRID, in 2016 and 2017, and one of the Outstanding Reviewers of the IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON

POWERSYSTEMS, in 2017 and 2018, and one of the Outstanding Reviewers of the IEEE OPENACCESSJOURNAL OFPOWER ANDENERGY(OAJPE), in 2020.

He is also the Volume Editor of the bookBlockchain-Based Smart Grids (Elsevier, 2020). He is a Top Scientist in the Guide2Research Ranking in computer science and electronics.

(12)

JOÃO P. S. CATALÃO (Senior Member, IEEE) received the M.Sc. degree from the Instituto Supe- rior Técnico (IST), Lisbon, Portugal, in 2003, and the Ph.D. degree and Habilitation for Full Profes- sor (‘‘Agregação’’) from the University of Beira Interior (UBI), Covilha, Portugal, in 2007 and 2013, respectively. He is currently a Professor with the Faculty of Engineering, University of Porto (FEUP), Porto, Portugal, and a Research Coordi- nator with INESC TEC. He was also appointed as a Visiting Professor with North China Electric Power University (NCEPU), Beijing, China. He was the Primary Coordinator of the EU-funded FP7 Project ‘‘Smart and Sustainable Insular Electricity Grids Under Large-Scale Renewable Integration’’ (SiNGULAR), a 5.2-million-euro project involv- ing 11 industry partners. He was also the Principal Investigator of three funded projects by the Portuguese National Funding Agency for Science, Research and Technology (FCT) and the European Regional Development Fund (FEDER). Moreover, he has authored or coauthored more than 945 pub- lications, including 460 international journal articles (more than 150 IEEE TRANSACTIONS/journal articles, 200 Elsevier, and 20 IET journal articles), 440 international conference proceedings papers (vast majority co-sponsored by IEEE), four books and 41 book chapters, with an H-index of 72, an i10- index of 381, and more than 20,900 citations (according to Google Scholar), having supervised more than 100 postdoctorals, Ph.D., and M.Sc. students, and students with project grants. His research interests include power system operations and planning, power system economics and electricity markets, distributed renewable generation, demand response, smart grid, and multi- energy carriers. He was the Inaugural Technical Chair of SEST 2018—

First International Conference on Smart Energy Systems and Technologies (technically co-sponsored by IEEE IES), the General Chair of SEST 2019 (technically co-sponsored by IEEE PES and IEEE IES), the General Co- Chair of SEST 2020 (technically co-sponsored by IEEE PES, IEEE IES, and IEEE IAS), and the Honorary Chair of SEST 2021 (technically co-sponsored by IEEE PES, IEEE IES, IEEE IAS, and IEEE PELS). He was also the Editor of the books entitledElectric Power Systems: Advanced Forecasting Techniques and Optimal Generation SchedulingandSmart and Sustainable Power Systems: Operations, Planning and Economics of Insular Electricity Grids(Boca Raton, FL, USA: CRC Press, 2012 and 2015, respectively).

He is an Associate Editor of the IEEE TRANSACTIONS ONSYSTEMS, MAN, and CYBERNETICS: SYSTEMS, the IEEE TRANSACTIONS ONNEURAL NETWORKS

ANDLEARNINGSYSTEMS, the IEEE TRANSACTIONS ONINDUSTRIALINFORMATICS, the IEEE TRANSACTIONS ONINTELLIGENTTRANSPORTATIONSYSTEMS, the IEEE

TRANSACTIONS ONVEHICULARTECHNOLOGY, the IEEE TRANSACTIONS ONCLOUD

COMPUTING, the IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON INDUSTRYAPPLICATIONS, the IEEE SYSTEMS JOURNAL, and IEEE ACCESS. He was the Inaugural Senior Edi- tor of the IEEE TRANSACTIONS ONSMARTGRIDand the Inaugural Promo- tion and Outreach (Senior) Editor of the IEEE OPENACCESS JOURNAL OF POWER AND ENERGY, 2020–2021, being also a member of the IEEE PES Publications Board. Furthermore, he was an Associate Editor of the IEEE TRANSACTIONS ONSUSTAINABLEENERGY, 2011–2018, the IEEE TRANSACTIONS ONSMARTGRID, 2013–2020, and the IEEE TRANSACTIONS ONPOWERSYSTEMS

and the IEEE POWERENGINEERINGLETTERS, 2017–2021. He was the Guest Editor-in-Chief of the Special Section on ‘‘Real-Time Demand Response’’

of the IEEE TRANSACTIONS ONSMARTGRID, published in December 2012, the Guest Editor-in-Chief for the Special Section on ‘‘Reserve and Flexibility for Handling Variability and Uncertainty of Renewable Generation’’ of the IEEE TRANSACTIONS ONSUSTAINABLEENERGY, published in April 2016, the Corresponding/Lead Guest Editor (Guest Editor-in-Chief) for the Special Section on ‘‘Industrial and Commercial Demand Response’’ of the IEEE TRANSACTIONS ONINDUSTRIALINFORMATICS, published in November 2018, the Guest Co-Lead Editor for the Special Section on ‘‘Invited Papers on Emerg- ing Topics in the Power and Energy Society’’ of the IEEE OPENACCESS

JOURNAL OFPOWER ANDENERGY, published in October 2020, the Guest Co- Lead Editor for the Special Section on ‘‘Invited Papers in 2021 on Emerg- ing Topics in the Power and Energy Society’’ of the IEEE OPENACCESS

JOURNAL OFPOWER ANDENERGY, published in November 2021, and the Guest Editor-in-Chief for the Special Section on ‘‘Demand Response Applications of Cloud Computing Technologies’’ of the IEEE TRANSACTIONS ONCLOUD

COMPUTING, to be published in January 2022. He was the recipient of the 2011 Scientific Merit Award UBI-FE/Santander Universities, the 2012 Scientific Award UTL/Santander Totta, the 2016–2019 (four years in a row) FEUP Diplomas of Scientific Recognition, the 2017 Best INESC-ID Researcher Award, and the 2018 Scientific Award ULisboa/Santander Universities. He was recognized as one of the Outstanding Associate Editors and Reviewers 2020 of the IEEE TRANSACTIONS ONSMARTGRID. He is a Top Scientist in the Guide2Research Ranking, which lists only scientists having H-index equal or greater than 40. He is also among the 0.5% Top Scientists, according to a study published by a team at Stanford University. Furthermore, he has won five Best Paper Awards at IEEE Conferences and the MPCE Best Paper Award 2019. Moreover, former M.Sc. and Ph.D. students have won the National Engineering Award 2011, the first Prize in REN (Portuguese TSO) Award 2019, and the first Prize in 2020 Young Engineer Innovation Award.

Viittaukset

LIITTYVÄT TIEDOSTOT

In the trading layer, participants (sellers and buyers) trade flexibility in each time slot. The time slots for trading flexibility need to be small in a way that

ated with electricity market prices and the output power of renewable

 Introducing the Supply Share Index (SSI) to evaluate the competitive situation among the WPPs and to provide sensitivity analysis to investigate the effect of

This paper proposes monopolistic and game-based approaches for the management of energy flexibility through end-users, aggregators, and the Distribution System Operator (DSO) which

The concept of P2P trading was introduced for different scale of energy trading to increase democracy and exploit peers' maximum resource potential for producing energy

Abstract — In this paper, a stochastic decision making framework is presented in which a wind power producer (WPP) provides some required reserve capacity from demand response

Although the time-related latency does not seem to matter in the local environment with a limited number of prosumers, it may cause problems for the system with a large number of

The growing energy demand and irregularity in power supply, requires the government to find way to enhance energy investment interests especially from private